Federal Communications Commission FCC 10-58 Before the Federal Communications Commission Washington, D.C. 20554 In the Matter of Connect America Fund A National Broadband Plan for Our Future High-Cost Universal Service Support ) ) ) ) ) ) ) WC Docket No. 10-90 GN Docket No. 09-51 WC Docket No. 05-337 NOTICE OF INQUIRY AND NOTICE OF PROPOSED RULEMAKING Adopted: April 21, 2010 Released: April 21, 2010 Comment Date: (60 days from publication in the Federal Register) Reply Comment Date: (90 days from publication in the Federal Register) By the Commission: Chairman Genachowski and Commissioners Copps, McDowell, Clyburn and Baker issuing separate statements. TABLE OF CONTENTS Heading Paragraph # I. INTRODUCTION.................................................................................................................................. 1 II. NOTICE OF INQUIRY ......................................................................................................................... 3 A. Background...................................................................................................................................... 3 1. Current High-Cost Support Programs ....................................................................................... 3 2. The Commission’s Hybrid Cost Proxy Model .......................................................................... 5 3. National Broadband Plan........................................................................................................... 9 4. The National Broadband Plan Model...................................................................................... 11 B. Discussion...................................................................................................................................... 13 1. Model ...................................................................................................................................... 14 a. Use of a Model..................................................................................................................17 b. Cost Basis for Support ...................................................................................................... 23 c. Types of Models ............................................................................................................... 31 (i) HCPM vs. New Model ............................................................................................... 31 (ii) Total Costs vs. Incremental Costs .............................................................................. 33 (iii) Cost vs. Cost and Revenue......................................................................................... 35 d. Geographic Areas ............................................................................................................. 41 2. Expedited Process for Providing Funding to Extend Networks in Unserved Areas ............... 43 III. NOTICE OF PROPOSED RULEMAKING ........................................................................................ 49 A. Background.................................................................................................................................... 49 B. Discussion...................................................................................................................................... 51 1. Controlling the Size of the High-Cost Program ...................................................................... 51 2. Specific Steps to Cut Legacy High-Cost Support ................................................................... 53 IV. PROCEDURAL MATTERS................................................................................................................ 63 Federal Communications Commission FCC 10-58 2 A. Initial Regulatory Flexibility Analysis........................................................................................... 63 B. Paperwork Reduction Act Analysis ............................................................................................... 64 C. Ex Parte Presentations .................................................................................................................. 65 D. Comment Filing Procedures .......................................................................................................... 66 V. ORDERING CLAUSES....................................................................................................................... 74 APPENDIX A: Initial Regulatory Flexibility Analysis APPENDIX B: Comments of 61 Economists APPENDIX C: Omnibus Broadband Initiative, The Broadband Availability Gap By the Commission: I. INTRODUCTION 1. On March 16, 2010, the Commission released a Joint Statement on Broadband stating that “[t]he nearly $9 billion Universal Service Fund (USF) and the intercarrier compensation (ICC) system should be comprehensively reformed to increase accountability and efficiency, encourage targeted investment in broadband infrastructure, and emphasize the importance of broadband to the future of these programs.” 1 On the same day, the Commission delivered to Congress a National Broadband Plan recommending that the Commission adopt cost-cutting measures for existing voice support and create a Connect America Fund (CAF), without increasing the overall size of the Fund, to support the provision of broadband communications in areas that would be unserved without such support or that depend on universal service support for the maintenance of existing broadband service. 2 2. Today’s notice of inquiry (NOI) and notice of proposed rulemaking (NPRM) is the first in a series of proceedings to implement that vision. This proceeding will develop the detailed analytic foundation necessary for the Commission to distribute funds in an efficient, targeted manner that avoids waste and minimizes burdens on American consumers. The NOI seeks comment on whether the Commission should use a model to help determine universal service support levels in areas where there is no private sector business case to provide broadband and voice services. The NOI also seeks comment on the best way to create an accelerated process to target funding toward new deployment of broadband networks in unserved areas, while we are considering final rules to implement fully a new CAF funding mechanism that efficiently ensures universal access to broadband and voice services. Finally, the accompanying NPRM seeks comment on specific common-sense reforms to cap growth and cut inefficient funding in the legacy high-cost support mechanisms and to shift the savings toward broadband communications. II. NOTICE OF INQUIRY A. Background 1. Current High-Cost Support Programs 3. The purpose of high-cost universal service support always has been to help ensure that consumers have access to telecommunications services in areas where the cost of providing such services would otherwise be prohibitively high. The current system of high-cost support has achieved 1 Joint Statement on Broadband, GN Docket No. 10-66, Joint Statement on Broadband, FCC 10-42 (rel. Mar.16, 2010) at 2. 2 Federal Communications Commission, Connecting America: The National Broadband Plan, (rel. Mar. 16, 2010) (National Broadband Plan) at 144. Federal Communications Commission FCC 10-58 3 considerable success, helping ensure access to affordable voice services in all regions of the nation. 3 However, it was not designed to universalize broadband. 4 Today, federal high-cost support is provided through a complicated patchwork of programs, developed over decades, in which the types of support a carrier receives depends on the size and regulatory classification of the carrier, not the characteristics of the area to which support is directed. 5 Because only voice is a supported service, there is no requirement to provide broadband service to consumers, nor is there any mechanism to ensure that support is targeted toward extending broadband service to unserved areas. 6 Moreover, some of the current high-cost programs do not provide support in an economically efficient manner. For example, eligibility for certain types or levels of support is based on company size or regulatory classification, rather than the cost of serving the area. 7 In addition, several programs provide support based on an incumbent carrier’s embedded costs, whether or not a competitor provides, or could provide, service at a lower cost. 4. In the Universal Service First Report and Order, the Commission found that “the proper measure of cost for determining the level of universal service support is the forward-looking economic cost of constructing and operating the network facilities and functions used to provide the supported services.” 8 Prior to the Telecommunications Act of 1996, 9 explicit federal universal service support was based on embedded costs. In setting forth the framework for implementing the 1996 Act, the Commission found that “the use of embedded cost to calculate universal service support would lead to subsidization of inefficient carriers at the expense of efficient carriers and could create disincentives for 3 The Commission’s most recent report on telephone subscribership, released in February 2010, found that the telephone subscribership penetration rate in the United States in 2009 had increased to 95.7 percent – the highest reported penetration rate since the Census Bureau began collecting such data in November 1983. Industry Analysis and Technology Division, Wireline Competition Bureau, Telephone Subscribership in the United States, 3 (February 2010) (Telephone Subscribership Report). 4 See National Broadband Plan at 135. 5 The federal high-cost support mechanism includes five major components. High-cost loop support provides support for intrastate network costs to rural incumbent local exchange carriers (LECs) in service areas where the cost to provide service exceeds 115 percent of the national average. See 47 C.F.R. § 36.631. Rural incumbent LECs may also receive support under two additional sub-mechanisms in limited circumstances. Carriers may qualify for additional support, i.e., safety net additive support, if they demonstrate significant investment in infrastructure. See 47 C.F.R. § 36.605. Carriers may be eligible for additional support, i.e., safety value support, in instances where they acquire exchanges and invest in that infrastructure. See 47 C.F.R. § 54.305(d). Local switching support provides intrastate support for switching costs for companies that serve 50,000 or fewer access lines. See 47 C.F.R. § 54.301. High-cost model support provides support for intrastate network costs to non-rural incumbent LECs in states where the cost to provide service in non-rural areas exceeds two standard deviations above the national average cost per line. See 47 C.F.R. § 54.309. Interstate access support (IAS) provides support for price cap carriers to offset certain reductions in interstate access charges. See 47 C.F.R. § 54.800-809. Interstate common line support (ICLS) provides support to rate-of-return carriers, to the extent that subscriber line charge (SLC) caps do not permit such carriers to recover their interstate common line revenue requirements. See 47 C.F.R. § 54.901- 904. 6 See National Broadband Plan at 141. 7 Small carriers typically receive considerably more per-line support than larger carriers serving high-cost geographic areas. 8 See Federal-State Joint Board on Universal Service, CC Docket No. 96-45, Report and Order, 12 FCC Rcd 8776, 8899, para. 224 (1997) (Universal Service First Report and Order) (subsequent history omitted). 9 Telecommunications Act of 1996, Pub. L. No. 104-104, 110 Stat. 56 (1996 Act). The 1996 Act amended the Communications Act of 1934. 47 U.S.C. § 151, et seq. (Communications Act or Act). Federal Communications Commission FCC 10-58 4 odel. carriers to operate efficiently.” 10 In 1997, the Commission determined that, initially, the larger, i.e., “non- rural,” carriers, such as the Regional Bell Operating Companies, would transition to receiving support based on forward-looking economic cost, and that the smaller, i.e., “rural,” carriers, would gradually shift to a support system based on forward-looking economic cost after further review. 11 Subsequently, in 2001, the Commission adopted modified embedded cost support rules for rural carriers pending more comprehensive reform. 12 As a consequence, only non-rural high-cost support is based on forward- looking economic cost, as determined by the Commission’s voice telephony cost m 13 2. The Commission’s Hybrid Cost Proxy Model 5. In 1997, the Commission adopted ten criteria to be used in estimating the forward- looking economic cost of providing universal service in high-cost areas and thereby ensure economically efficient levels of support. 14 For example, the “technology assumed in the . . . model must be the least- cost, most-efficient, and reasonable technology for providing the supported services that is currently being deployed.” 15 Because existing incumbent local exchange carrier plant in a particular area may not reflect forward-looking technology or design choices, the costs estimated by the model “must not be the embedded cost of the facilities, functions, or elements.” 16 Instead, the model “must be based upon an examination of the current cost of purchasing facilities and equipment.” 17 To reflect the economies of scale associated with the provision of multi-line business, special access, and private lines, the model “must estimate the cost of providing service for all businesses and households within a geographic 10 Universal Service First Report and Order, at 8901, para. 228. 11 Id. at 8889, paras. 203-204. 12 See Federal-State Joint Board on Universal Service, Multi-Association Group (MAG) Plan for Regulation of Interstate Services of Non-Price Cap Incumbent Local Exchange Carriers and Interexchange Carriers , CC Docket Nos. 96-45, 00-256 Fourteenth Report and Order and Twenty-Second Order on Reconsideration, Report and Order, 16 FCC Rcd 11244, 11248, para. 8 (2001) (Rural Task Force Order). Based on the Rural Task Force proposals, the Commission adopted modified embedded cost rules to provide support to rural carriers for a five-year period. Over the next few years, the Commission had planned to develop a “long-term universal service plan for rural carriers that is better coordinated with the non-rural mechanism,” and “that better targets support to carriers serving high-cost areas.” Id. The Commission stated that “in developing a long-term universal service plan that better targets support to the highest cost rural areas, we intend to consider all options, including the use of forward-looking costs, to determine appropriate support levels for both rural and non-rural carriers.” Id. at 11310, para. 170. The Commission further indicated that, although it believed that distinct rural and non-rural mechanisms were appropriate at that time, two distinct mechanisms might not be viable in the long term. Id. In 2004, the Commission asked the Joint Board to review the Commission’s rules regarding high-cost support for rural carriers and to determine the appropriate rural mechanism to succeed the five-year plan adopted in the Rural Task Force Order. See Federal-State Joint Board on Universal Service, CC Docket No. 96-45, Order, 19 FCC Rcd 11538 (2004) (Rural Referral Order). Although the Commission originally intended that the rules adopted in the Rural Task Force Order would remain in place for five years, the Joint Board had not completed its review and recommendations by 2006. The Commission extended those rules until such time that it “adopts new high-cost support rules for rural carriers.” Federal-State Joint Board on Universal Service; High-Cost Universal Service Support, CC Docket No. 96-45, WC Docket No. 05-337, Order, 21 FCC Rcd 5514, 5515, para. 2 (2006). 13 See infra para. 6. 14 See Universal Service First Report and Order, 12 FCC Rcd at 8912-16, para. 250. 15 Id. at 8913, para. 250 (criterion one). 16 Id. (criterion three). 17 Id. Federal Communications Commission FCC 10-58 5 region.” 18 To enable all interested parties to review and comment on the model and its inputs, “all underlying data, formulae, computations, and software must be available,” and all underlying data should be verifiable. 19 To provide transparency and flexibility, the cost model “must include the capability to examine and modify the critical assumptions and engineering principles.” 20 6. Using the ten criteria to provide guidance for selecting a cost model and its input values, the Commission, between 1997 and 1999, developed its current forward-looking economic cost model, called the Hybrid Cost Proxy Model (HCPM), in an open, deliberative process in which industry experts, state commissions, staff of the Federal-State Joint Board on Universal Service, and other interested parties provided valuable assistance. 21 First, the Commission looked at the network design, engineering, and technology issues relevant to constructing a network to provide the supported services and adopted the model “platform,” i.e., assumptions about the design of the network and network engineering, and fixed characteristics such as soil and terrain. 22 Second, the Commission looked at the costs of the components of the network, such as cable and switch costs, plant maintenance expenses, and various capital cost parameters, and adopted the model input values. 23 The Commission developed an extensive record 18 Id. at 8915, para. 250 (criterion six). 19 Id. (criterion eight). 20 Id. (criterion nine). 21 See, e.g., Common Carrier Bureau to Post on the Internet Modifications to the Forward-Looking Economic Cost Model for Universal Service Support, Public Notice, CC Docket Nos. 96-45, 97-160, 14 FCC Rcd 1893 (1998); Common Carrier Bureau Releases Preliminary Common Input Values to Facilitate Selection of Final Input Values for the Forward-Looking Cost Model for Universal Service, Public Notice, CC Docket Nos. 96-45, 97-160,14 FCC Rcd 2372 (1999); Common Carrier Bureau Releases Preliminary Results Using Proposed Input Values in the Forward-Looking Cost Model for Universal Service, Public Notice, CC Docket Nos. 96-45, 97-160, 14 FCC Rcd 9648 (1999); Common Carrier Bureau Releases Revised Spreadsheet for Estimating Universal Service Support Using Proposed Input Values in the Forward-Looking Cost Model, Public Notice, CC Docket Nos. 96-45, 97-160, 14 FCC Rcd 11313(1999). The Wireline Competition Bureau was previously named the Common Carrier Bureau. HCPM is available for downloading on the Commission’s Web site at http://www.fcc.gov/wcb/tapd/hcpm/welcome.html. 22 Federal-State Joint Board on Universal Service, Forward-Looking Mechanism for High-Cost Support for Non- Rural LECs, Fifth Report and Order, CC Docket Nos. 96-45, 97-160, 13 FCC Rcd 21323, 21330 (1998) (Fifth Report and Order). The model platform adopted by the Commission combined elements from each of the three models considered in that proceeding: (1) the BCPM, Version 3.0 (BCPM); (2) the HAI Model, Version 5.0a (HAI); and (3) the Hybrid Cost Proxy Model, Version 2.5 (HCPM). BCPM was submitted by BellSouth, US WEST, Inc., and Sprint. HAI was submitted by AT&T and MCI. HCPM was developed by Commission staff. 23 Federal-State Joint Board on Universal Service, Forward-Looking Mechanism for High Cost Support for Non- Rural LECs, Tenth Report and Order, CC Docket Nos. 96-45, 97-160, 14 FCC Rcd 20156 (1999) (Tenth Report and Order), affirmed, Qwest Corp. v. FCC, 258 F.3d 1191 (10 th Cir. 2001) (Qwest I). In the companion Ninth Report and Order, the Commission also adopted the methodology for determining high-cost support for non-rural carriers. Federal-State Joint Board on Universal Service, Ninth Report and Order and Eighteenth Order on Reconsideration, CC Docket 96-45, 14 FCC Rcd 20432 (1999) (Ninth Report and Order), remanded, Qwest I, 258 F.3d 1191; Federal-State Joint Board on Universal Service, Order on Remand, Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, and Memorandum Opinion and Order, CC Docket 96-45, 18 FCC Rcd 22559 (2003), remanded, Qwest Communications Int’l, Inc. v. FCC, 398 F.3d 1222 (10 th Cir. 2005) (Qwest II); High-Cost Universal Service Support; Federal-State Joint Board on Universal Service, FCC 10-56, Order on Remand and Memorandum Opinion and Order (2010) (rel. April 16, 2010) (Qwest II Remand Order). The forward-looking cost mechanism takes the costs generated by the cost model, compares statewide average costs to a national benchmark, and provides support to non-rural carriers in those states where the costs exceed that benchmark. This mechanism became effective January 1, 2000. On July 31, 2001, the United States Court of Appeals for the Tenth Circuit affirmed the Commission’s use of the cost model (continued….) Federal Communications Commission FCC 10-58 6 posed (Continued from previous page) before adopting its high-cost universal service model, including issuing two further notices of pro rulemaking, 24 providing additional guidance to parties submitting cost models, 25 and conducting several series of workshops on model platform and inputs issues and numerous ex parte meetings. 26 7. The Commission recognized that “the task of establishing a model to estimate forward- looking costs is a dynamic process that will need to be reviewed and adjusted periodically,” 27 and that “the model must evolve as technology and other conditions change.” 28 Although the Commission’s forward-looking economic cost model used to determine non-rural support was adopted more than a decade ago, it has not been comprehensively updated. It estimates the costs of a narrowband, circuit- switched network that provides “plain old telephone service,” whereas today’s most efficient providers are constructing fixed or mobile networks that are capable of providing broadband as well as voice services. Not only are the model inputs out-of-date, but the technology assumed by the model no longer reflects “the least-cost, most-efficient, and reasonable technology for providing the supported services that is currently being deployed.” 29 8. Today, a significant portion of current high-cost support is provided to both incumbent telephone companies and competitive telephone companies based on an incumbent carrier’s embedded costs, regardless of whether a competitor could provide service at a lower cost. In 2009, the Commission and deferred to the Commission’s expertise in establishing the cost model’s technical specifications. See Qwest I, 258 F.3d at 1205-06. 24 See Federal-State Joint Board on Universal Service, Forward-Looking Mechanism for High-Cost Support for Non-Rural LECs, Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, CC Docket Nos. 96-45, 97-160, 12 FCC Rcd 18514 (1997) (1997 Further Notice); Federal-State Joint Board on Universal Service, CC Docket No. 96-45, Forward- Looking Mechanism for High-Cost Support for Non-Rural LECs, Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, CC Docket No. 97-160, FCC 99-120 (rel. May 28, 1999), 64 Fed. Reg. 31,780 (June 14, 1999) (1999 Further Notice). 25 See, e.g., Guidance to Proponents of Cost Models in Universal Service Proceeding: Customer Location and Outside Plant, Public Notice, CC Docket Nos. 96-45, 97-160, 12 FCC Rcd 18340 (1997); Guidance to Proponents of Cost Models in Universal Service Proceeding: Switching, Interoffice Trunking, Signaling, and Local Tandem Investment, Public Notice, CC Docket Nos. 66-45, 97-160, 13 FCC Rcd 5884 (1998); Common Carrier Bureau Requests Further Comment on Selected Issues Regarding the Forward-Looking Economic Cost Mechanism for Universal Service, Public Notice, CC Docket Nos. 96-45, 97-160, 13 FCC Rcd 9346 (1998); Common Carrier Bureau Seeks Comment on Model Platform Development, Public Notice, CC Docket Nos. 97-160, 13 FCC Rcd 21680 (1998). 26 See, e.g., Weekly Meetings on Forward-Looking Cost Mechanism for Universal Service Support, Public Notice, CC Docket Nos. 96-45 and 97-160, 12 FCC Rcd 22481 (1997); Workshops on Forward-Looking Cost Mechanisms for Universal Service Support for Non-Rural Carriers, September 3 and September 11, 1997, Public Notice, CC Docket Nos. 96-45 and 97-160, 13 FCC Rcd 4276 (1998); Common Carrier Bureau to Hold Three Workshops on Input Values to be Used to Estimate Forward-Looking Economic Costs for Purposes of Universal Service Support, Public Notice, CC Docket Nos. 96-45, 97-160, 13 FCC Rcd 23728 (1998). 27 Fifth Report and Order, 13 FCC Rcd at 21330, para. 13. 28 Tenth Report and Order, 14 FCC Rcd at 20170, para. 28. When the Commission adopted the model platform, it delegated to then Common Carrier Bureau (now the Wireline Competition Bureau) (Bureau) the authority to make technical changes “as necessary and appropriate” on an ongoing basis to ensure that the model operates as the Commission intended. See Fifth Report and Order, 13 FCC Rcd at 21330, para. 13. Pursuant to this delegated authority, the Bureau has made technical changes to the model platform and limited changes to the input values, such as updating annual line counts. The Bureau last updated the lines used in the model to estimate costs in 2003 (using year-end 2002 lines), and non-rural high-cost support has been based on these cost estimates since 2004. 29 Universal Service First Report and Order, 12 FCC Rcd at 8913, para. 250 (criterion one). Federal Communications Commission FCC 10-58 7 disbursed almost $4.3 billion in high-cost support, of which $331 million was calculated on the basis of forward-looking costs. 30 3. National Broadband Plan 9. On March 16, 2010, the Commission delivered to Congress the National Broadband Plan, which recommends the creation of a Connect America Fund to address the broadband availability gap in unserved areas and to provide any ongoing support necessary to sustain service in areas that require public funding, including those areas that already may have broadband. 31 The National Broadband Plan recommends that the Commission direct public investment toward meeting an initial national broadband availability target of 4 Mbps of actual download speed and 1 Mbps of actual upload speed. 32 The National Broadband Plan used an initial target of 4 Mbps actual download speed and 1 Mbps of actual upload speed to develop an analysis of the number of people that lack access to broadband capability today. The National Broadband Plan estimated that 14 million people living in seven million housing units in the United States currently do not have access to terrestrial broadband infrastructure capable of meeting this target, described as “the broadband availability gap.” 33 10. The National Broadband Plan states that the Commission’s “long range goal should be to replace all the legacy High-Cost programs with a new program that preserves the connectivity that Americans have today and advances universal broadband in the 21 st century.” 34 Specifically, the National Broadband Plan recommends that the Commission create a new Connect America Fund, and that the CAF should adhere to the following principles: (1) “CAF should only provide funding in geographic areas where there is no private sector business case to provide broadband and high-quality voice-grade service;” (2) “There should be at most one subsidized provider of broadband per geographic area;” (3) “The eligibility criteria for obtaining broadband support from CAF should be company- and technology- agnostic so long as the service provided meets the specifications set by the FCC;” (4) “The FCC should identify ways to drive funding to efficient levels, including market-based mechanisms where appropriate, to determine the firms that will receive CAF support and the amount of support they will receive;” and (5) “Recipients of CAF support must be accountable for its use and subject to enforceable timelines for achieving universal access.” 35 In addition, the National Broadband Plan recommends that the Commission “create a fast-track program in CAF for providers to receive targeted funding for new broadband construction in unserved areas,” 36 and create a Mobility Fund “to provide one-time support for deployment of 3G networks, to bring all states to a minimum level of 3G (or better) mobile service availability.” 37 4. The National Broadband Plan Model 11. The National Broadband Plan concludes that private investment alone is unlikely to extend broadband in some areas of the country with low population density. In particular, “[b]ecause service providers in these areas cannot earn enough revenue to cover the costs of deploying and operating 30 Universal Service Administrative Company 2009 preliminary disbursement data. 31 See National Broadband Plan, at 135. 32 Id. 33 Id. at 136. 34 Id. at 145. 35 Id. (footnotes omitted). 36 Id. at 144. 37 Id. at 146. Federal Communications Commission FCC 10-58 8 broadband networks, including expected returns on capital, there is no business case to offer broadband services in these areas.” 38 12. To estimate the amount of additional funding required to close the broadband availability gap, Commission staff developed an economic model to estimate the level of additional funding that would be required to extend broadband service to the estimated 7 million housing units that presently are unserved by broadband that provides 4 Mbps actual download speed, 1 Mbps upload speed, and acceptable quality of service for the most common interactive applications. 39 First, Commission staff developed a baseline of the current state of broadband availability and infrastructure deployment throughout the nation, which included all the major types of terrestrial broadband infrastructure as they are deployed today, and as they likely will evolve over the next three to five years without public support. 40 Because the Commission does not presently have access to a comprehensive data set, at the required level of geographic granularity, regarding availability (i.e., which people have access to what services) and infrastructure (i.e., which people are passed by what types of network hardware), Commission staff combined several data sets and supplemented nationwide data with the output of a large multivariate regression model. Staff then used this regression model to predict availability by speed tier and to fill gaps, especially last mile gaps, in the infrastructure data. 41 Second, building on the infrastructure data, known and inferred, Commission staff’s economic analysis calculated the incremental forward-looking cost of upgrading or extending existing infrastructure to provide broadband service consistent with the national broadband availability target, and the incremental revenues that might be expected to be generated by the network upgrades. From this, they calculated the net present value (NPV) of the gap between incremental costs and expected incremental revenues of broadband deployments in unserved areas. This NPV represents the amount of additional funding necessary to upgrade or extend existing infrastructure to the level necessary to support the target (4 Mbps download/1 Mbps upload). 42 Underlying the economic model is the principle that only profitable business cases will induce incremental network investments and the best measure of profitability is the net present value of a build. 43 B. Discussion 13. The National Broadband Plan recommends establishing the CAF to support universal access to broadband and voice services, including providing any ongoing support necessary to sustain service in areas that already have broadband because of the existing high-cost universal service program. 44 As a first step in comprehensive universal service reform, we seek comment on three discrete groups of issues. First, we seek comment on use of a model as a competitively neutral and efficient tool for helping us to quantify the minimum amount of universal service support necessary to support networks that provide broadband and voice service, such that the contribution burden that ultimately falls on American consumers is limited. Second, we seek comment on potential approaches to providing such targeted funding on an accelerated basis in order to extend broadband networks in unserved areas, such as a competitive procurement auction. Third, in the accompanying NPRM, we seek comment on specific 38 Id. at 136. 39 Omnibus Broadband Initiative, The Broadband Availability Gap (OBI Technical Paper No. 1) at 1-3 (OBI, The Broadband Availability Gap); see Appendix C. 40 Id. at 1. 41 Id. at 1-2. 42 Id. at 2-3. 43 Id. at 1. 44 National Broadband Plan at 144. Federal Communications Commission FCC 10-58 9 proposals to cap and cut the legacy high-cost programs and realize savings that can be shifted to targeted investment in broadband infrastructure. 45 We encourage input from Tribal governments on all of these issues, and specifically ask whether there are any unique circumstances in Tribal lands that would necessitate a different approach. 46 Similarly, we request comment on whether there are any unique circumstances in insular areas that would necessitate a different approach. 1. Model 14. We specifically seek comment on whether the Commission should use the National Broadband Plan model as the starting point for developing a cost model, or alternatively a cost/revenue model, to use in determining future support for broadband-capable networks that provide voice service. We seek comment on whether the analysis and economic model that Commission staff used to estimate the broadband availability gap in unserved areas provides a useful foundation for calculating the support levels needed for the CAF in a way that minimizes waste, fraud and abuse. We also seek comment on what modifications to the National Broadband Plan model would be required if the CAF is eventually to replace all of the legacy high-cost programs. 15. A detailed description of the National Broadband Plan model, The Broadband Availability Gap, is found in Appendix C and is available on the Commission’s Broadband.gov Web site. 47 Additional model documentation includes technical documentation of how the model is constructed and more detail about the statistical model used to estimate availability and network infrastructure in areas where no data are available, which also will be available on Broadband.gov. A public notice will be released shortly regarding a workshop to discuss the technical paper. 16. Commenters are invited to comment on any aspect of the National Broadband Plan model that may be relevant to our consideration of how to reform the existing universal service support mechanisms. We highlight below only selected details relating to the National Broadband Plan model methodology, and specifically seek comment on several threshold design principles the Commission may consider before issuing a further notice of proposed rulemaking in this proceeding. a. Use of a Model 17. We seek comment on whether the Commission should develop a nationwide broadband model to estimate support levels for the provision of broadband and voice service in areas that are currently served by broadband with the aid of legacy high-cost support, as well as areas that are unserved. A federal model could provide a more uniform and equitable basis for determining support than 45 See infra section III. 46 For the purposes of this NPRM, we define “Tribal lands” as any federally recognized Indian tribe’s reservation, pueblo or colony, including former reservations in Oklahoma, Alaska Native regions established pursuant to the Alaska Native Claims Settlement Act (85 Stat. 688), and Indian allotments. The term “Tribe" means any American Indian or Alaska Native Tribe, Band, Nation, Pueblo, Village or Community which is acknowledged by the Federal government to have a government-to-government relationship with the United States and is eligible for the programs and services established by the United States. See Statement of Policy on Establishing a Government-to- Government Relationship with Indian Tribes, 16 FCC Rcd 4078, 4080 (2000). Thus, “Tribal lands” includes American Indian Reservations and Trust Lands, Tribal Jurisdiction Statistical Areas, Tribal Designated Statistical Areas, and Alaska Native Village Statistical Areas, as well as the communities situated on such lands. This would also include the lands of Native entities receiving Federal acknowledgement or recognition in the future. Although Native Hawaiians are not currently members of federally-recognized Tribes, we also seek comment on whether there are any unique circumstances that would warrant an alternative approach in Native Hawaiian homelands. 47 See http://www.broadband.gov/plan/broadband-working-reports-technical-papers.html. Federal Communications Commission FCC 10-58 10 individual carrier cost studies or models submitted by interested parties. 48 A uniform federal model could provide a mechanism for determining support levels based on the geographic characteristics of the areas served, rather than the regulatory classification of the incumbent telephone company that serves the area. 18. One assumption underlying the National Broadband Plan’s estimate of the level of public support needed to fill the broadband availability gap is that “whenever possible, a market-based mechanism will be used to select which providers receive support,” . . . “and that there is competitive interest in receiving a subsidy to extend broadband to an unserved area.” 49 One of the principles underlying the creation of the CAF is that the Commission “should identify ways to drive funding to efficient levels, including market-based mechanisms where appropriate, to determine firms that will receive CAF support and the amount of support they will receive.” 50 19. The Commission has previously sought comment on using competitive bidding – that is, using a reverse auction, in which sellers, rather than buyers, compete and the lowest bid wins – to determine high-cost support amounts for voice telephony. 51 It tentatively concluded that “reverse auctions offer several potential advantages over current high-cost support distribution mechanisms.” 52 The Commission reasoned that “[i]f a sufficient number of bidders compete in an auction, the winning bid might be close to the minimum level of subsidy required to achieve the desired universal service goals.” 53 Similarly, the National Broadband Plan states that “[i]f enough carriers compete for support in a given area and the mechanism is properly designed, the market should help identify the provider that will serve the area at the lowest cost.” 54 20. We seek comment on whether a model would be an important tool, even if the Commission uses a market-based mechanism to identify supported entities and support levels under the CAF. For example, if the Commission uses some form of a reverse auction to determine CAF support levels, it would be important to establish a “reserve price,” i.e., a maximum subsidy level that participants would be allowed to place as a bid, because there may be few bidders in certain geographic areas. Depending on the design of the market-based mechanism, reserve prices could play a critical role. A reserve price that is set too low is likely to discourage bidders from participating, while one that is set too high raises the possibility that too much support will be allocated to a particular area. 48 The Commission encourages interested parties to submit such information on the record, however, to assist us in developing an accurate and verifiable federal cost model. The Commission previously concluded that a national forward-looking model would provide a more consistent approach and found that relying on differing forward- looking cost methodologies would prevent meaningful comparisons and provide a less accurate picture of relative forward-looking costs. See Federal-State Joint Board on Universal Service, Access Charge Reform, Seventh Report & Order and Thirteenth Order on Reconsideration in CC Docket No. 96-45, Fourth Report & Order in CC Docket No. 96-262, and Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, 14 FCC Rcd 8078, 8104, para. 52 (1999). 49 National Broadband Plan at 137. 50 Id. at 145. 51 Specific examples of reverse auctions include procurement auctions to identify the party willing to provide a good or service at the lowest cost to the buyer, and auctions to identify the least amount of support needed to induce a party to undertake a certain action. 52 High-Cost Universal Service Support, Federal-State Joint Board on Universal Service, WC Docket No. 05-337, CC Docket No. 96-45, Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, 23 FCC Rcd 1495, 1500 para. 11 (2008) (Reverse Auctions Notice). 53 Id. 54 National Broadband Plan at 145. Federal Communications Commission FCC 10-58 11 21. If we ultimately use some form of market-based mechanism to determine CAF support, we seek comment on whether a model should be used to set reserve prices. Specifically, we seek comment on whether a model would provide advantages over the alternative of using a particular firm’s current support levels to set reserve prices. Currently, high-cost support levels for voice telephony are based on statewide or study area average costs. 55 Moreover, high-cost support is based on the incumbent telephone companies’ forward-looking or embedded costs to provide voice service, which is not necessarily the same as the costs of an efficient provider of both broadband and voice services. Some areas where broadband is not available today may be unserved because there is insufficient high-cost support available in the area to make a business case for deploying broadband-capable networks. In these cases, setting the reserve price at the current support levels could result in a reserve price that is too low and would not further our goal of extending broadband-capable networks to unserved areas. In other cases, setting the reserve price at current support levels could result in a reserve price that is too high, which would not help us “identify ways to drive funding to efficient levels.” 56 22. In addition to assisting the Commission in setting reserve prices, we seek comment on whether a model could be an important tool in determining appropriate support amounts (for example, in areas where the Commission determines that it is unable to use a competitive bidding mechanism). We also seek comment on the role of a model in identifying the most costly areas to serve, where the Commission may want to consider alternative approaches to providing access to broadband and voice services. 57 For example, the National Broadband Plan’s estimate of the $24 billion broadband availability gap is based on the economics of terrestrial technologies only and on the assumption that satellite capacity in the foreseeable future does not appear sufficient to serve every unserved household. 58 The National Broadband Plan estimated that the most expensive 250,000 unserved housing units represent a disproportionate share of the total investment gap – $14 billion. 59 This represents less than two-tenths of one percent of all housing units in the United States; the average amount of funding for terrestrial broadband per household to close the gap for these units is an estimated $56,000. 60 b. Cost Basis for Support 23. We seek comment on whether the Commission should base any new CAF support on the forward-looking economic costs of an efficient provider, rather than on historic, embedded costs. Basing support on forward-looking costs is consistent with the Commission’s policy adopted in the Universal Service First Report and Order that support in high-cost areas should be based on forward-looking economic costs and the Commission’s finding that using embedded costs to calculate support would lead 55 To the extent that certain types of support may be targeted to wire centers, UNE zones, or disaggregated in some rural study areas, overall support levels are still determined based upon statewide or study area averages. 56 National Broadband Plan at 145. 57 See id. at 150 (suggesting that the Commission “should consider alternative approaches, such as satellite broadband, for addressing the most costly areas of the country to minimize the contribution burden on consumers across America”). 58 National Broadband Plan at 137. (“While satellite is capable of delivering speeds that meet the National Availability Target, satellite capacity can meet only a small portion of broadband demand in unserved areas for the foreseeable future. Satellite has the advantage of being both ubiquitous and having a geographically independent cost structure, making it particularly well suited to serve high-cost, low-density areas. However, while satellite can serve any given household, satellite capacity does not appear sufficient to serve every unserved household.”) (footnotes omitted). 59 Id. at 138. 60 Id. Federal Communications Commission FCC 10-58 12 to inefficient subsidization of carriers and could create disincentives for carriers to operate efficiently. 61 Using forward looking costs also is consistent with the National Broadband Plan’s recommendation that “CAF support levels should be based on what is necessary to induce a private firm to serve an area,” and that “[s]upport should be based on the net gap (i.e., forward looking costs less revenues).” 62 24. In addition, we seek comment on what technology platforms should be included in the forward-looking cost model if the Commission decides to base broadband support on the forward-looking economic costs of an efficient provider. The National Broadband Plan recommended that eligibility for obtaining Connect America Funding “should be company- and technology-agnostic,” 63 which is consistent with the “competitively neutrality” principle adopted by the Commission in the Universal Service First Report and Order. 64 The plan recommends that “[s]upport should be available to both incumbent and competitive telephone companies (whether classified today as ‘rural’ or ‘non-rural’), fixed and mobile wireless providers, satellite providers and other broadband providers, consistent with statutory requirements.” 65 We seek comment on this proposal to ensure competitive neutrality. 25. Consistent with the principle that eligibility for obtaining CAF support should be technology-agnostic, we seek comment on whether the Commission should develop a model that estimates the costs of all technologies currently being deployed (or soon to be deployed) that are capable of providing voice service and broadband service that meets the national broadband availability target. We also seek comment on how to ensure that any cost model used in conjunction with determining CAF support is capable of identifying the least-cost, most-efficient technology in unserved areas. A forward- looking economic cost model that estimates the costs of various technologies would enable the Commission to identify the least-cost, most-efficient technology currently being deployed, and thereby, provide only as much support as needed to achieve the Commission’s goals for universal access. 26. We note, however, that while the costs of providing satellite service do not vary with geography and are fairly easy to identify, at present there is not sufficient satellite capacity to address all of the households that are unserved. 66 Thus we do not believe that we need to include satellite in the model. We seek comment on that view. 27. In defining forward-looking economic cost, we seek comment on the extent to which the Commission should consider any existing plant. We note in this regard that the Commission’s forward- looking cost model adopted a “scorched node” approach, which assumed the incumbent LECs’ central office (switch) locations as a given, rather than a total green field approach. 67 The National Broadband Plan model assumes existing infrastructure (for example, central office locations, cell towers), and estimates the incremental costs of brown field build outs and estimates green field build only where there is no nearby infrastructure. We seek comment on what existing infrastructure the model should assume. 61 See supra para. 4. 62 National Broadband Plan at 145. 63 Id. 64 Universal Service First Report and Order, 12 FCC Rcd at 8801, para. 47 (explaining that “competitive neutrality means that universal service support mechanisms and rules neither unfairly advantage or disadvantage one provider over another, and neither unfairly favor or disfavor one technology over another”). 65 National Broadband Plan at 145. 66 Id. at 137. 67 See, e.g., Universal Service First Report and Order, Appendix J, 12 FCC Rcd at 9435, n. 628 (“A ‘scorched node’ model is one that models the network using the existing wire centers. A ‘greenfield’ model, by contrast, does not use the existing wire centers, but models a completely new network, including new wire centers.”). Federal Communications Commission FCC 10-58 13 We also seek comment on which nodes are most analogous to a LEC central office in a scorched node approach for different technologies. 28. The Commission has extensive experience modeling the costs of wireline deployment, but prior to the National Broadband Plan proceeding, had not modeled the costs of deploying alternative technologies. Although the National Broadband Plan model includes wireless technologies, Commission staff noted that “[i]t is important to recognize that a wireless network has several layers of complexity that are not found in wireline networks, each of which affect the user experience and, therefore, network buildout costs and the investment gap.” 68 For example, the user experience may be affected by the distance of the user from a cell site, the number of users sharing spectrum within a cell, the characteristics of the terrain, and the capability of end-user devices. We therefore seek comment on what modifications to the National Broadband Plan model, if any, would be appropriate to estimate wireless costs for purposes of universal service support. 29. Commission staff noted that determining the actual cost of a wireless deployment would require a finely calibrated propagation model. 69 However, Commission staff noted that conducting the radiofrequency (RF) propagation analysis in the field that would be required to calibrate such a model would be extremely time-consuming and expensive. According to Commission staff, such analysis is usually undertaken only at the time of an actual build-out, and may still not account for some effects, such as seasonal foliage. We seek comment on whether a propagation model would be required to accurately model the costs of wireless deployment. We also seek comment on the feasibility of developing such a model. 30. In the absence of a finely calibrated propagation model, Commission staff used a combination of approaches to ensure both adequate coverage and sufficient capacity to ensure access to service consistent with the target speed. The maximum cell radius is calculated from target uplink signal strength, with the radius in any given area adjusted for likely terrain-driven signal degradation. Capacity requirements for downlink capacity for the number of modeled end-users in a given cell drive cell splitting as required. Nonetheless, Commission staff concedes that “it is possible that the parameters in an actual network deployment are different from those that we estimated.” 70 We seek comment on the assumptions underlying the parameters that the National Broadband Plan model uses to estimate the costs of a wireless network capable of providing service that provides 4 Mbps actual download and 1 Mbps actual upload capabilities. Is the National Broadband Plan approach an appropriate way to model wireless deployment costs for purposes of determining CAF support? c. Types of Models (i) HCPM vs. New Model 31. We seek comment on whether the Commission should develop a new model for determining appropriate universal service support levels for modern networks, rather than updating and modifying the Commission’s existing HCPM used to determine high-cost support for the provision of voice telephony by non-rural carriers. Although the Commission previously stated that its forward- looking economic cost model should evolve as technology changes, 71 we do not believe that we should use the Commission’s existing model as a starting point in developing a model to estimate CAF support 68 OBI, The Broadband Availability Gap at 66. 69 Id. 70 Id. 71 See Fifth Report and Order, 13 FCC Rcd at 21330, para. 13; Tenth Report and Order, 14 FCC Rcd at 20170, para. 28. Federal Communications Commission FCC 10-58 14 levels. Since the Commission adopted its model, much progress has been made in developing computer cost models that estimate the cost of constructing modern networks. For example, in a 2009 notice of inquiry, the Commission sought comment on one such model. 72 More recently, Commission staff utilized CostQuest Associates as a contractor in developing the National Broadband Plan model that estimated the size of the broadband availability gap. 32. The National Broadband Plan model has several advantages over the Commission’s existing HCPM that reflect improvements in cost modeling that have occurred within the industry and outside of Commission proceedings over the last several years. For example, the National Broadband Plan model relies on road and other rights-of-way data to route outside plant, which is a more realistic method than the Commission’s existing model’s use of rectilinear distances. 73 In addition, the National Broadband Plan model estimates the costs of multiple broadband technologies. Although the Commission’s existing model could be modified relatively easily to estimate the costs of providing digital subscriber line (DSL) service over shorter copper loops by changing certain input values, 74 HCPM does not estimate the costs of other technologies such as wireless, hybrid fiber-coaxial cable, or fiber-to-the- premises, whereas the National Broadband Plan model does. The National Broadband Plan model also includes the costs of so-called “middle mile” facilities, whereas the only transport costs that HCPM estimates are the incumbent LECs’ inter-office transport costs. We seek comment on whether the National Broadband Plan model is a better starting point for developing a broadband cost model than the Commission’s existing HCPM. We seek comment on what other models we should consider if the Commission determines that it should develop a new model. (ii) Total Costs vs. Incremental Costs 33. We seek comment on using a forward-looking economic cost model to determine support for broadband that estimates the total costs of broadband-capable networks, rather than the incremental costs of upgrading or extending existing networks to provide broadband in unserved areas. As noted above, the National Broadband Plan model identifies “unserved areas,” i.e. areas without infrastructure that is capable of delivering broadband service meeting the national target, and estimates the incremental cost of augmenting existing infrastructure to provide broadband using various technologies. As discussed more fully below, the National Broadband Plan model estimates not only the incremental costs of deploying broadband to unserved areas, but also the expected incremental revenues associated with the new broadband deployment. 75 The National Broadband Plan model, however, does not take into account universal service support received under the current high-cost programs for those unserved areas. Rather, the National Broadband Plan model estimates only the incremental support amounts needed to deploy broadband in unserved areas and “assumes that existing networks will be available on an ongoing basis” 72 See Federal-State Joint Board on Universal Service, High-Cost Universal Service Support, CC Docket No. 96-45, WC Docket No. 05-337, Notice of Inquiry, 24 FCC Rcd 4281, 4286-87 (2009) (seeking comment on CostQuest proposal that the Commission adopt an advanced services model for use in a reformed universal service system). See also, Comments of CostQuest Associates, CC Docket Nos. 96-45, 96-98, 99-68, 99-200, 01-92, WC Docket Nos. 03-109, 04-36, 05-337, 06-122 (filed Nov. 26, 2008) (CostQuest Comments) (attaching, among other things, a white paper by James Stegeman, Dr. Steve Parsons, and Mike Wilson, The Advanced Services Model: Proposal for a Competitive and Efficient Universal Service High-Cost Approach for a Broadband World (CostQuest Proposal)). 73 See CostQuest Proposal at 22-26. 74 Specifically, we could change the maximum copper loop length, which is currently set at 18,000 feet, to the maximums used in the broadband model (12,000, 5,000, and 3,000 feet), and update other inputs to include the costs of Digital Subscriber Line Access Multiplers (DSLAMs). We note however, that other inputs also should be updated to reflect current costs. 75 See infra paras. 35-40. Federal Communications Commission FCC 10-58 15 d build-out. without taking into consideration the role of existing universal service support. 76 For example, if a carrier in a high-cost area uses high-cost support to make voice and broadband available to eighty-five percent of its customers, the National Broadband Plan model estimates the cost of deploying broadband to the remaining fifteen percent, but does not estimate the costs associated with the eighty-five percent that already have access to broadband. The National Broadband Plan model does not estimate forward- looking economic costs in areas with existing broadband networks and, thus, provides no means of objectively evaluating whether current high-cost support levels are efficient, or how much support would be necessary to maintain broadband and voice services in areas currently receiving high-cost support. Nor does the National Broadband Plan model take into account any universal service support that carriers may currently receive for providing supported telephony services, whether or not they provide broadband. 34. The Commission’s forward-looking cost model that is used to determine support for non- rural carriers estimates the total local exchange network costs of providing telephone service to all households and businesses within a geographic area. We seek comment on whether, if the Commission replaces its current high-cost funding mechanism with a new Connect America Fund to support both broadband and voice service, the Commission should adopt a total cost rather than an incremental cost model. (iii) Cost vs. Cost and Revenue 35. We seek comment on whether the Commission should consider revenues, as well as costs, in determining CAF support. The Commission’s current forward-looking cost model used to determine support levels for voice telephony for non-rural carriers estimates only costs, not revenues. 77 In contrast, the National Broadband Plan model, in addition to estimating the incremental costs of deploying broadband in unserved areas, estimates the expected incremental revenue from the new customers and services resulting from the new broadban 78 36. The National Broadband Plan recommends that support should be based on the net gap, i.e., forward-looking costs less revenues and that “[r]evenues should include all revenues earned from broadband-capable network infrastructure, including voice, data and video revenues, and take into account the impact of other regulatory reforms that may impact revenue flows, such as ICC [intercarrier compensation], and funding from other sources, such as Recovery Act grants.” 79 Because “[s]imply calculating the incremental costs of deploying broadband is not enough to determine the Broadband Investment Gap necessary to encourage operators to deploy,” the National Broadband Plan model estimates “the amount of support necessary to cause the networks’ economics to not only be positive, but to be sufficiently positive to motivate investment given capital scarcity and returns offered by alternative investments.” 80 76 OBI, The Broadband Availability Gap at 35 (“One issue with this approach is that it assumes that existing networks will be available on an ongoing basis. To the extent that existing networks depend on public support, such as USF disbursements, the total gap for providing service in unserved areas could be significantly higher than the incremental calculation indicates.”). 77 None of the current high-cost support mechanisms consider expected revenues, except in the limited circumstances when subscriber line charge (SLC) revenues are imputed for purposes of calculating interstate common line support (ICLS). For example, high-cost loop support and local switching support are based on embedded costs without regard to revenues. 78 OBI, The Broadband Availability Gap at 34-35, 45-50. 79 National Broadband Plan at 145 (footnotes omitted). 80 OBI, The Broadband Availability Gap at 33. Two key principles underlying the OBI model’s design are that “[o]nly profitable business cases will induce incremental network investments” and that “[i]nvestment decisions are made on the incremental value they generate.” Id. Federal Communications Commission FCC 10-58 16 37. We seek comment on whether to take into account the revenues earned from all services provided over broadband networks in calculating support under the CAF, such as broadband and video revenues, as opposed to basing support only on costs. If we include video revenues, should we also take into account costs associated with the provision of video services, such as programming costs? We seek comment on potential methods for estimating revenues and what revenues should be included, if the Commission were to consider revenues, as well as costs, in determining CAF support. We recognize that different services may be available in different parts of the country, and prices may vary in different areas. We also recognize that take rates for various services may vary depending upon a number of demographic factors. For example, the National Broadband Plan model uses demographic factors to estimate broadband adoption rates at the census block level. 81 What information should the Commission use in order to take into account revenues in determining support levels? 38. If the Commission were to include revenues in a model to determine broadband support, we seek comment on the methodology that the National Broadband Plan model uses to estimate incremental revenues. Incremental revenue in the National Broadband Plan model is the product of two main components: the number of incremental customers and the average revenue per user (ARPU). 82 The Commission staff analysis recognizes that some key assumptions on which the model is based may have a “disproportionately large” impact on the size of the investment gap. 83 Two of these major assumptions relate to the revenue calculation: “[t]he take rate for broadband in unserved areas will be comparable to the take rate in served areas with similar demographics;” and “[t]he average revenue per product or bundle will evolve slowly over time.” 84 To estimate broadband adoption rates, Commission staff used broadband-adoption survey data that broke out responses by various demographic factors and a widely accepted technology adoption mathematical model to develop take rates for every census block in the nation. 85 These census block penetration rates were then scaled to estimate the take rate of related services (voice, video), the effect of bundled services, and the stratification of tiering (basic vs. premium). 86 To develop an approximation for ARPU, Commission staff estimated an individual ARPU value for each product category (data, voice, and video), as well as an ARPU value for the product bundle, and a low and high version of the data, voice, video and bundle product categories to reflect customer segmentation. 87 39. We seek comment on the time frame within which any model can be expected reliably to forecast expected revenues. The National Broadband Plan model calculates the NPV of cash flows over 20 years. A forward-looking cost model estimates the costs of technologies currently being deployed and reasonably accurate input values can be developed by looking at current costs and equipment lifetimes. 81 The OBI analysis assumes, however, that the take rate for broadband in unserved areas will be the same as in served areas with similar demographics. See infra para. 38. 82 OBI, The Broadband Availability Gap at 35. The number of incremental customers is based on the technology modeled so that revenues are not double counted. For example, if the model calculates the costs of shortening loop lengths to deliver data and video services, only incremental data and video related revenue would be considered; voice revenues would not be included. Id. 83 Id. at 42. 84 Id. 85 See id. at 45-50. The demographic variables used in the National Broadband Plan model that were positively correlated with broadband adoption were: income greater than $100,000; income between $75,000 – $100,000; college degree or greater education. Those that were negatively correlated were: less than high school education; senior citizen (65+); rural; and high school degree only. Id. at 45. 86 See id. at 48-49.. 87 See id. at 50-51 & Exhibit 3-V. Federal Communications Commission FCC 10-58 17 try The Commission staff estimate of revenues is primarily based on current prices and forecasts, although the revenue attributed to incremental voice revenue for telephone companies is set equal to the ARPU for a similar cable Voice over Internet Protocol (VoIP) product to account for recent market trends. How often should a revenue model be updated to reflect changes in prices and market trends? If calculations are made for a shorter time period, how should the model account for the residual value of assets whose lifetimes are longer than the study period (e.g., how does one account for the residual value of fiber in a ten-year study)? 40. The National Broadband Plan model uses 11.25% as the discount rate, identifies the expected cash flows associated with building and operating a network over the project’s lifetime of 20 years, and computes the net present value of those cash flows. 88 We seek comment on whether this is an appropriate approach for purposes of determining CAF support amounts. We also seek comment more generally on how often key model inputs should be updated. d. Geographic Areas 41. The National Broadband Plan model initially estimates the incremental costs of deploying broadband to unserved areas and the incremental revenues associated with that deployment at a very granular geographic level, the census block. 89 Commission staff reasoned that using the average cost per household of existing deployments, even if adjusted for differences in population density, would risk underestimating costs because unserved areas tend to have much lower densities than the coun overall. 90 Although geographic granularity is important in capturing the real costs associated with providing broadband service in rural and remote areas, Commission staff concluded that it does not make sense to evaluate whether to build a network at the census block level. 91 In the real world, private sector firms typically will evaluate the profitability of deployment decisions at a larger, more aggregated service-area level than a census block. 92 Commission staff concluded that estimating lowest-cost technologies on a census block basis could lead to an unrealistic patchwork quilt of different technologies in contiguous census blocks and aggregated financial outputs to the county level. Thus, the National Broadband Plan model estimates the amount of additional funding required to close the broadband availability gap by assessing the gap of various technologies at the county level. 93 42. We seek comment on what geographic area the Commission should use in calculating the cost of deploying a network and providing services, and on whether the Commission should use neutral geographic units, as recommended in the National Broadband Plan. 94 We seek comment on the advantages and disadvantages of using a particular geographic area to determine either the costs or the gap between costs and revenues. As Commission staff explains, if the geography is too big, there will be portions that would be more efficiently (less expensively) served by an alternate technology, but if the 88 OBI, The Broadband Availability Gap at 33. 89 One of the key principles underlying the model’s design is: “Capturing the local (dis-)economies of scale that drive local profitability requires granular calculations of costs and revenues.” Id. 90 Id. at 38; see also id. at 8-9 & Exhibits 1-E, 1-F. 91 Id. at 36. 92 Another key principle underlying the model’s design is: “Network-deployment decisions reflect service-area economies of scale.” Id. at 35. 93 Id. at 37. 94 See National Broadband Plan at 145 (“The FCC should evaluate eligibility and define support levels on the basis of neutral geographic units such as U.S. Census-based geographic areas, not the geographic units associated with any particular industry segment.”). Federal Communications Commission FCC 10-58 18 geography is too small it will be subscale, thereby leading to more inefficiency and higher costs (and support levels). The National Broadband Plan model uses counties because they “appear large enough in most cases to provide the scale benefits but not so large as to inhibit the deployment of the most cost- effective technology,” while remaining technology neutral. 95 We seek comment on whether this is a workable approach for future CAF universal service funding decisions. 2. Expedited Process for Providing Funding to Extend Networks in Unserved Areas 43. We believe that it is critical to constrain growth in the legacy high-cost support mechanisms while we develop rules for a more efficient and accountable universal service funding mechanism. At the same time, we recognize that firms today are upgrading and modernizing their networks to offer a wide array of new services to consumers. The National Broadband Plan recommends that the Commission “create a fast-track program in CAF for providers to receive targeted funding for new broadband construction in unserved areas.” 96 Such funding could, for instance, be provided to areas identified as “unserved” once the Broadband Data Improvement Act mapping is completed in February 2011. 97 We seek comment on the best way to create an accelerated process to distribute funding to support new deployment of broadband-capable networks in unserved areas during the period we are considering final rules to implement fully the new CAF funding mechanism. In particular, we seek comment on whether there is an efficient method for delivering a set amount of support, which does not require the use of a model. 44. For example, shortly after passage of the American Recovery and Reinvestment Act, 98 a group of economists recommended that a competitive procurement auction be used to allocate funding under the Recovery Act. 99 The group noted that “it is difficult to design a grant application system to ensure that firms receive only the minimum subsidy necessary to achieve the goal.” 100 They argued that 95 OBI, The Broadband Availability Gap at 37. 96 National Broadband Plan at 144. 97 See Broadband Data Improvement Act of 2008, Pub. L. No. 110-385, 122 Stat. 4096 (codified at 47 U.S.C. §§ 1301-1304) (BDIA). On July 2, 2009, the National Telecommunications Information Agency (NTIA) released a Notice of Funding Availability (NOFA), which defined several key terms for the purposes of the state broadband program. Department of Commerce, National Telecommunications and Information Administration, State Broadband Data and Development Grant Program, Docket No. 0660-ZA29, Notice of Funds Availability, 74 Fed. Reg. 32545, 32555 (July 8, 2009) (NTIA State Mapping NOFA). The NOFA defines “broadband” to include data- transmission technology with advertised speeds of at least 768 kbps downstream and at least 200 kbps upstream to end users. NTIA State Mapping NOFA, 74 Fed. Reg. at 32548. An area is “unserved” for purposes of the NOFA if 90% of households in the area lack access to facilities-based terrestrial broadband service. Id. NTIA later issued a clarification of the Technical Appendix to the NTIA State Mapping NOFA, and provided additional guidance to its implementation of the Program by posting responses to Frequently Asked Questions. See Department of Commerce, National Telecommunications and Information Administration, State Broadband Data and Development Grant Program, Docket No. 0660-ZA29, Notice of Funds Availability; Clarification. 74 Fed. Reg. 40569 (Aug. 12, 2009); NTIA, State Broadband Data and Development Program (Broadband Mapping Program) Frequently Asked Questions, http://www.ntia.doc.gov/broadbandgrants/BroadbandMappingFAQs%20_090812.pdf (rel. Aug. 12, 2009) (NTIA Aug. 12 FAQs). 98 American Recovery and Reinvestment Act of 2009, Pub. L. No. 111-5, 123 Stat. 115 (2009) (Recovery Act). The Recovery Act was signed into law on February 17, 2009. 99 Paul Milgrom, Gregory Rosston, Andrzej Skrzypacz & Scott Wallston, “Comments of 61 Concerned Economists: Using Procurement Auctions to Allocate Broadband Stimulus Grants,” (April 13, 2009) (submitted to NTIA and Rural Utilities Service (RUS)) (61 Economists’ Proposal); see Appendix B. 100 Id. at 2. Federal Communications Commission FCC 10-58 19 “[a]n objective, ‘mechanistic’ approach that applies specific, quantitative criteria can be both easier to implement and lead to more efficient outcomes than traditional grant application review.” 101 Among other things, such an approach can “inherently induce firms to contribute their own investment to increase the chance that their bid is accepted.” 102 45. The procurement auction proposal by this group of economists is similar in many ways to reverse auction proposals that have been previously considered by the Commission. In any reverse auction procedure, it is necessary to establish precise definitions of what parties are asked to bid for, including the geographic boundaries of the areas to be served and a precise definition of the service quality that winning bidders would be expected to provide. 103 The economists’ proposal potentially differs from some reverse auction proposals in that bidding parties themselves would be allowed to specifically define the geographic units and other service characteristics associated with their bids. 104 To select winning proposals from those submitted, it would therefore be necessary to establish a scoring rule such that all proposals could be evaluated on an easily understood and unambiguous basis. Such a mechanism could be implemented relatively quickly without addressing the full complexities inherent in other reverse auction proposals. For example, it would not require the development of a cost or cost and revenue model to set reserve prices. In addition, it would minimize the potential problem with reverse auctions concerning few bidders in a specific area, because proposals for different areas would compete against each other. Thus, all bids for all unserved areas in the United States would be competing for a limited, defined amount of funding. There are limitations with such an approach, however. For instance, because this approach involves one-time grants, it does not appear suitable for areas where operating costs exceed revenues and thus where continuing support is required. 46. The National Broadband Plan concluded that “[i]n some areas, subsidizing all or part of the initial capex will allow a service provider to have a sustainable business. Elsewhere, subsidizing initial capex will not be enough; service providers will need support for continuing costs.” 105 Based on available information, Commission staff estimated that “[s]upport for one-time deployment or upgrades will likely be enough to provide broadband to 46% of the seven million unserved housing units.” 106 The National Broadband Plan stated that “USF resources are finite, and policymakers need to weigh tradeoffs in allocating those resources . . .” and recommended as a guiding principle that policymakers should seek to “maximize the number of households that are served by broadband meeting the National Broadband Availability Target.” 107 If the Commission has a finite amount of funding available in a given year to support the new deployment of broadband-capable networks, could a competitive procurement auction be used to maximize the number of households that would gain access to broadband? 47. We seek comment on whether some form of competitive procurement auction could be an efficient mechanism to determine subsidies for the extension of new broadband-capable infrastructure in unserved areas. For instance, could such a competitive process be used to target one-time subsidies to extend broadband-capable networks in areas where revenues are likely to be sufficient to cover ongoing 101 Id. at 3. 102 Id. at 4. 103 For example, build-out requirements and minimum speed and other quality standards would be pre-specified. 104 Some reverse auction proposals have suggested a package bidding format based on pre-defined geographic units such as counties. Under the economists’ proposal, bidders would be allowed to propose arbitrary geographic units based on their own business models. 105 National Broadband Plan at 138. 106 Id. 107 Id. at 143. Federal Communications Commission FCC 10-58 20 costs of operation? 108 We also seek comment on the appropriate scoring function to use if a procurement auction mechanism is adopted for this purpose. The economists’ proposals suggests that “[t]his could be a simple metric, such as ‘newly served population’ (defined as the population to which service above a minimum bandwidth threshold is newly available) or a more involved measure such as ‘effective bandwidth supplied’ (defined as the population to which service is newly available adjusted for the speed of service).” 109 One important aspect of a scoring rule is the set of weights used to evaluate new service to unserved areas based on perceived cost or customer density. For example, a simple rule that ranks proposals based on the minimum subsidy required per newly served household would tend to favor proposals to serve relatively low cost regions. We invite specific comments on rules that could be used to evaluate proposals to provide differing speeds of access in excess of 4 Mbps actual download and 1 Mbps actual upload, or differing qualities of access. 48. Parties are also invited to comment specifically on any other aspects of the procurement auction mechanism outlined in the economists’ proposal, including build-out requirements and compliance and auditing features. For instance, what would be an appropriate time frame in which the winning bidder must make the required investment? What percentage of the winning bid should be provided before construction begins, and what conditions must a recipient meet before remaining installments are paid? What certifications regarding performance should be made, and how should the Commission verify that conditions have been satisfactorily met? III. NOTICE OF PROPOSED RULEMAKING A. Background 49. The Commission has acknowledged the benefits of comprehensive reform of the current high-cost mechanisms. 110 Indeed, the Joint Statement on Broadband recommends that the universal service fund and the intercarrier compensation system “be comprehensively reformed to increase accountability and efficiency, encourage targeted investment in broadband infrastructure, and emphasize the importance of broadband to the future of these programs.” 111 The National Broadband Plan recommends significant changes to the current high-cost program, and this notice of proposed rulemaking 108 By “one-time” we refer to a fixed amount of subsidy that could be paid in installments. 109 61 Economists’ Proposal, at 5-6; see Appendix B. 110 See, e.g., High-Cost Universal Service Support, Federal-State Joint Board on Universal Service, WC Docket No. 05-337, CC Docket No. 96-45, Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, 23 FCC Rcd 1467 (2008) (Identical Support Rule Notice); High-Cost Universal Service Support, Federal-State Joint Board on Universal Service, WC Docket No. 05- 337, CC Docket No. 96-45, Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, 23 FCC Rcd 1495 (2008) (Reverse Auctions Notice); High-Cost Universal Service Support, Federal-State Joint Board on Universal Service, WC Docket No. 05-337, CC Docket No. 96-45, Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, 23 FCC Rcd 1531 (2008) (Joint Board Comprehensive Reform Notice); High-Cost Universal Service Reform; Federal-State Joint Board on Universal Service; Lifeline and Link Up; Universal Service Contribution Methodology; Numbering Resource Optimization; Implementation of the Local Competition Provisions in the Telecommunications Act of 1996; Developing a Unified Intercarrier Compensation Regime; Intercarrier Compensation for ISP-Bound Traffic; IP-Enabled Services, CC Docket Nos. 96-45, 99-200, 96-98, 01-92, 99-68, WC Docket Nos. 05-337, 03-109, 06-122, 04-36, Order on Remand and Report and Order and Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, 24 FCC 6475 (2008) (Comprehensive Reform FNPRM), aff’d Core Communications, Inc. v.FCC, 592 F.3d 139 (D.C. Cir. 2010). 111 Joint Statement on Broadband, GN Docket No. 10-66, Joint Statement on Broadband, FCC 10-42, para 3 (rel. Mar. 16, 2010) (Joint Statement on Broadband). Federal Communications Commission FCC 10-58 21 (NPRM) represents an important first step in seeking public comment on the roadmap to universal access to broadband. 112 50. The National Broadband Plan recommends that the Commission cut inefficient funding of legacy voice service and refocus universal service funding to directly support modern communications networks that will provide broadband as well as voice services. 113 In this NPRM, we propose to contain growth in legacy high-cost support mechanisms as a critical first step to transitioning to a more efficient and accountable funding mechanism, recognizing that consumers across America ultimately pay for universal service. We propose specific reforms to the legacy high-cost program that could be initially implemented to create a pathway to a more efficient and targeted mechanism for funding broadband. We seek comment on these proposals. We encourage input from everyone. We are particularly interested in input from Tribal governments on these specific proposals, and we specifically ask whether there are any unique circumstances in Tribal lands that would necessitate a different approach. Similarly, we request comment on whether there are any unique circumstances in insular areas that would necessitate a different approach. B. Discussion 1. Controlling the Size of the High-Cost Program 51. As an essential first step toward repurposing the universal service fund to support broadband as well as voice service, we must ensure that the size of the fund remains reasonable. The National Broadband Plan recommends that the Commission take steps to manage the universal service fund so that its total size remains close to its current level (in 2010 dollars) to minimize the burden of increasing universal service contributions on consumers. 114 The Commission already has taken action to control the overall size of the high-cost fund. In 2008, the Commission adopted on an interim basis an overall competitive ETC high-cost cap of approximately $1.4 billion, pending comprehensive USF reform. 115 Similarly, today we seek comment on capping legacy high-cost support provided to incumbent telephone companies at 2010 levels, which would have the effect of creating an overall ceiling for the legacy high-cost program. 116 Such a cap would remain in place while the Commission determines how to distribute funds in a more efficient, targeted manner to those areas of the country where no firm can operate profitably without government support, while minimizing burdens on American consumers who ultimately pay for universal service through carrier pass-through charges. 112 The American Recovery and Reinvestment Act of 2009 required the Commission to deliver a National Broadband Plan to Congress. See Pub. L. No. 111-5, 123 Stat. 115 (2009). The Commission delivered the National Broadband Plan to Congress on March 16, 2010. FCC Sends National Broadband Plan to Congress, FCC News Release (dated Mar. 16, 2010). Federal Communications Commission, Connecting America: The National Broadband Plan, Ch. 8 (rel. March 16, 2010) (National Broadband Plan). 113 National Broadband Plan at 147-48. 114 National Broadband Plan at 149. 115 High-Cost Universal Service Support; Federal-State Joint Board on Universal Service, WC Docket No. 05-337, CC Docket No. 96-45, Order, 23 FCC Rcd 8834 (2008), aff’d, Rural Cellular Ass’n v. FCC, 588 F.3d 1095 (D.C. Cir. 2009). The Commission adopted a limited exception to the cap for competitive ETCs serving tribal lands or Alaska Native regions. 116 In 2007, the Federal-State Joint Board on Universal Service recommended an overall cap for the high-cost support mechanisms and a transition in which existing funding mechanisms would be reduced, and all, or a significant share, of savings transferred to proposed new funds for broadband and mobility. High-Cost Universal Service Support; Federal-State Joint Board on Universal Service, WC Docket No. 05-337, CC Docket No. 96-45, Recommended Decision, 22 FCC Rcd 20477, 20484, paras. 26-27 (Fed.-State Jt. Bd. 2007). Federal Communications Commission FCC 10-58 22 52. We seek comment on how the Commission could implement such a cap. Alternatively, we invite other proposals that would ensure that the overall size of the high-cost fund stays at or below current levels. Should the Commission impose an overall cap on legacy high-cost support for incumbent LECs at 2010 levels? Should the Commission impose a cap on each individual high-cost mechanism (to the extent each is not already capped) at 2010 levels? Should the Commission freeze per-line support for each carrier at 2010 levels? For example, the Alliance for Rural CMRS Carriers proposed that incumbent LEC support amounts per line be capped at either March 2008 or March 2010 levels. 117 We seek comment on this proposal. Alternatively, should the Commission freeze the total amount of support a carrier receives in a particular study area at 2010 levels? Are there other ways to implement such a cap? What rule changes would be required to implement this proposal? How would the Commission implement this proposal in conjunction with the reforms identified in the following paragraphs? In addition, what implications would this proposal have for other Commission rules, such the Commission’s current pricing rules, and should the implementation of this proposal be coordinated with any other regulatory actions? 2. Specific Steps to Cut Legacy High-Cost Support 53. As discussed in more detail below, the National Broadband Plan identifies several specific first steps that could reduce funding in the legacy high-cost support mechanisms and recommends that those savings be used to further the goals of universalizing broadband without increasing the overall size of the universal service fund. The National Broadband Plan recognizes that shifting funds could have transitional impacts and recommends that “[a]s the FCC considers this policy shift, it should take into account the impact of potential changes in free cash flows on providers’ ability to continue to provide voice service and on future broadband network deployment strategies.” 118 Below, we seek comment on the first steps set forth in the National Broadband Plan. To the extent that any commenter believes that these proposals, or the proposal to cap legacy high-cost support, would negatively affect affordable voice service for consumers today, we would encourage such a commenter to identify all assumptions and to provide data, including information on network investment plans over the next five years and free cash flows, to support that position. The intent of these proposals is to eliminate the indirect funding of broadband-capable networks today through our legacy high-cost programs, 119 which is occurring without transparency or accountability for the use of funds to extend broadband service. We seek comment on the timing of implementing such reforms in conjunction with the creation of a more efficient and targeted 117 See Letter from David LaFuria, Counsel for Alliance for Rural CMRS Carriers, to Marlene H. Dortch, Secretary, FCC, CC Docket No. 96-45, WC Docket No. 05-337, GN Docket No. 09-47, 09-51, 09-137 (Mar. 3, 2010) (urging the FCC to adopt an interim cap for incumbent telephone company support per line at either March 2010 or March 2008 levels, pending comprehensive USF reform). Specifically, the Alliance for Rural CMRS Carriers propose that: 1) ILECs would receive the amount of per-line support they are eligible to receive as of the effective date of the cap (either March 2008 or March 2010) until comprehensive reform of the federal universal service support mechanism is implemented; 2) Beginning on the date that the interim plan commences, ILEC support would be calculated each quarter by simply determining whether an ILEC’s support has increased on a per-line basis since the effective date of the cap (either March 2008 or March 2010); 3) If an ILEC’s per-line support has increased, support would be determined by multiplying the current number of access lines in service by the capped per-line amount; 4) If the ILEC’s per-line support has decreased, then it will receive its support without any adjustments. 118 National Broadband Plan at 147. 119 Under the Commission’s so-called “no barriers” policy, high-cost support for voice services indirectly supports the deployment of broadband capable networks. See Rural Task Force Order, 16 FCC Rcd at 11322, para. 200 (“The public switched telephone network is not a single-use network. Modern network infrastructure can provide access not only to voice services, but also to data, graphics, video, and other services. . . . Thus, although the high- cost loop support mechanism does not support the provision of advanced services, our policies do not impede the deployment of modern plant capable of providing access to advanced services.”). Federal Communications Commission FCC 10-58 23 framework that will provide support for broadband and voice. We encourage commenters to address when each rule change should be implemented and how specific reforms should be sequenced to provide regulatory clarity for ongoing private sector investment. 54. In addition, we seek comment on the relationship between such universal service reforms and carriers’ rates, including intercarrier compensation rates, under the Commission’s current pricing rules. 120 We seek comment both on the likely rate impacts under existing pricing rules that would arise from the possible universal service reforms and any appropriate responses. We also note that many rural rate-of-return carriers participate in the National Exchange Carrier Association (NECA) pooling process for their interstate access charges. If universal service support under the legacy programs were frozen for such carriers, are there special considerations resulting from operation of the NECA pool that would unfairly advantage or disadvantage certain carriers? The Commission previously has expressed concern about the risks of continued participation in NECA pools by carriers that were subject to incentive regulation. 121 We seek comment on whether such concerns would remain if all rate-of-return carriers converted to incentive regulation. Would the pool be able to continue to operate pursuant to regulation other than rate-of-return? 55. Shifting Rate-of-Return Carriers to Incentive Regulation. The National Broadband Plan recommends that the Commission “require rate-of-return carriers to move to incentive regulation.” 122 We seek comment on requiring current rate-of-return companies to convert to some form of incentive regulation. We note that a number of companies have voluntarily converted to price cap regulation in the last two years. 123 In such cases, the Commission effectively converted the companies’ interstate common (continued….) 120 For example, under the Commission’s existing price cap rules, if a carrier no longer received IAS support to help meet its revenue requirement for particular regulated services, it could recover those revenues through new intercarrier compensation charges if its subscriber line charge (SLC) was at the applicable cap. 47 C.F.R. §§ 69.153 (presubscribed interexchange carrier charge), 69.154 (per-minute carrier common line charge). If the carrier’s SLC was not at the applicable cap, the carriers likely could seek an exogenous cost adjustment, resulting first in an increase in the SLC, and only then in new intercarrier compensation charges, to the extent that additional cost recovery was necessary. As another example, under the Commission’s price cap rules, price cap carriers are allowed to increase their price cap indices if their earnings fall below 10.25%. 47 C.F.R. § 61.45(d)(1)(vii). Price cap carriers forego this right, however, if they avail themselves of “pricing flexibility” regulatory relief. 47 C.F.R. § 69.731. 121 Multi-Association Group (MAG) Plan for Regulation of Interstate Services of Non-Price Cap Incumbent Local Exchange Carriers and Interexchange Carriers, Federal-State Joint Board on Universal Service, CC Docket Nos. 96-45, 00-256, Report and Order and Second Further Notice of Proposed Rulemaking, 19 FCC Rcd 4122, 4163, para. 91 (2004) (MAG Second Further Notice). 122 National Broadband Plan at 147. 123 A number of the mid-sized telephone companies recently have elected to convert to price-cap regulation. See Windstream Petition for Conversion to Price Cap Regulation and for Limited Waiver Relief, WC Docket No. 07- 171, Order, 23 FCC Rcd 5294 (2008) (Windstream Order); Petition of Puerto Rico Telephone Company, Inc. for Election of Price Cap Regulation and Limited Waiver of Pricing and Universal Service Rules; Consolidated Communications Petition for Conversion to Price Cap Regulation and for Limited Waiver Relief; Frontier Petition for Limited Waiver Relief upon Conversion of Global Valley Networks, Inc., to Price Cap Regulation, WC Docket Nos. 07-292, 07-291, 08-18, Order, 23 FCC Rcd 7353 (Wireline Comp. Bur. 2008); ACS of Alaska, Inc., ACS of Anchorage, Inc., ACS of Fairbanks, Inc. and ACS of the Northland, Inc., Petition for Conversion to Price Cap Regulation and Limited Waiver Relief, WC Docket No. 08-220, Order, 24 FCC Rcd 4664 (Wireline Comp. Bur. 2009); CenturyTel, Inc., Petition for Conversion to Price Cap Regulation and for Limited Waiver Relief, WC Docket No. 08-191, Order, 24 FCC Rcd 4677 (Wireline Comp. Bur. 2009). See also, e.g., Pleading Cycle Established for Comments on Vitelco Petition for Conversion to Price Cap Regulation and Other Limited Waiver Relief, WC Docket No. 10-39, Public Notice, DA 10-272 (rel. Feb. 18, 2010); Pleading Cycle Established for Federal Communications Commission FCC 10-58 24 al. line support (ICLS) to a frozen amount per line. We seek comment on whether the Commission should replace rate-of-return regulation with the price-cap framework recently adopted for voluntary conversions, 124 an alternative price-cap framework, or some other form of incentive regulation. 125 We seek comment on the costs and the benefits that would be realized by converting all rate-of-return carriers to price cap regulation or other incentive regulation. We seek comment on whether, in an increasingly competitive marketplace, and with carriers’ service offerings expanding beyond regulated services, the current rate-of-return framework, which considers only regulated costs and revenues, has become less appropriate. 56. We seek comment on whether we should convert ICLS to a frozen amount per line, which would have the effect of limiting growth in the legacy high-cost program. 126 We seek comment on whether this reform should be implemented at the same time as any measures the Commission may adopt to provide targeted funding for the deployment of broadband-capable infrastructure to areas that are unserved, or should such a rule change occur before the development of the CAF, or otherwise be coordinated with some other regulatory action such as conversion to incentive regulation. The National Broadband Plan recognizes that the savings realized by eliminating future growth in the legacy ICLS program represent funding that could be redirected toward achieving broadband-related goals. 127 We seek comment on this propos 57. Elimination of Interstate Access Support. The National Broadband Plan also recommends that the Commission “redirect access replacement funding known as Interstate Access Support (IAS) toward broadband deployment.” 128 Thus, we now seek comment on the elimination of interstate access support (IAS). When the Commission created IAS in 2000, it said that it would revisit (Continued from previous page) Comments on FairPoint Petition for Conversion to Price Cap Regulation and for Other Limited Waiver Relief, WC Docket No. 10-47, Public Notice, DA 10-299 (rel. Feb. 25, 2010); Pleading Cycle Established for Comments on Windstream Petition for Limited Waiver Relief, WC Docket No. 10-55, Public Notice, DA 10-397 (rel. Mar. 9, 2010). 124 In the Windstream Order, the Commission directed Windstream to establish initial price cap indexes for its price cap baskets using January 1st rates for the year of conversion and base period demand for the calendar year immediately prior to the conversion. The Commission required Windstream to target its average traffic-sensitive (ATS) rate to $0.0065 per ATS minute of use pursuant to section 61.3(qq) of the Commission’s rules, using an X- factor of 6.5 percent. Finally, the Commission granted Windstream a waiver to allow it to continue to receive ICLS for the converted study areas. Windstream was required to forego any recovery of a presubscribed interexchange carrier charge or carrier common line charge and forego assessing a $7.00 non-primary residential line subscriber line charge in conjunction with its receipt of frozen per-line ICLS. See generally, Windstream Order, 23 FCC Rcd 5294. 125 The Commission has sought comment in the past on other alternative incentive regulation schemes, and whether they might be appropriate for rate-of-return carriers. See, e.g., MAG Second Further Notice, 19 FCC Rcd at 4153- 64, paras. 68-94. 126 Specifically, in the Windstream Order, the Commission required that Windstream’s per-line ICLS be calculated at the preceding calendar year per-line disaggregated ICLS amounts, and frozen at those per-line levels going forward, and that its aggregate annual ICLS support be capped at an amount equal to its overall ICLS for the year preceding the conversion (after application of any required true-ups). Windstream Order, 23 FCC Rcd at 5302-04, paras. 20-21. As noted above, as a condition of its receipt of frozen per-line ICLS support, Windstream, among other things, committed to forgo the recovery of any PICC or CCL charge. Id. at 5300-01, para. 14. 127 National Broadband Plan at 147-148. 128 Id. at 147. Federal Communications Commission FCC 10-58 25 this funding mechanism “to ensure that such funding is sufficient, yet not excessive.” 129 That re- examination has not occurred. 58. Specifically, we now seek comment on eliminating sections 54.800-54.809 of our rules and transferring any IAS funding levels as of the date of elimination to the new Connect America Fund to provide support for broadband-capable networks. 130 We invite commenters to propose an appropriate timeline for the elimination of these rules and any glide-path that may be necessary to ensure that recipients continue to be able to provide voice services during the transition 59. Sprint and Verizon Wireless Voluntary Commitments. The National Broadband Plan also recommends that the Commission “issue an order to implement the voluntary commitments of Sprint and Verizon Wireless to reduce the high-cost funding they receive as competitive eligible telecommunications carriers to zero over a five-year period as a condition of earlier merger decisions.” 131 The Commission will consider shortly an order clarifying how to implement Verizon Wireless’s and Sprint’s voluntary commitments. 132 60. Elimination of Competitive ETC High-Cost Support. The National Broadband Plan recommends that the Commission phase out remaining competitive ETC funding under the existing funding mechanisms over a five-year period and target the savings toward the deployment of broadband- capable networks and other reforms in the plan. 133 We seek comment on this proposal. 61. We seek comment on whether we should ramp down competitive ETC support under the legacy programs, and if so, how the transition should occur. For example, should the Commission reduce support on a pro rata basis (e.g., 20% reduction each year) for each state? Should the Commission reduce support at an accelerated rate of decline? Should the Commission reduce support on a proportional basis for all states, or in some other manner, and if so, on what basis? Would there be any impact on existing 129 Access Charge Reform; Price Cap Performance Review for Local Exchange Carriers; Low-Volume Long Distance Users; Federal-State Joint Board on Universal Service, CC Docket Nos. 96-262, 94-1, 99-249, 96-45, Sixth Report and Order, Report and Order, and Eleventh Report and Order, 15 FCC Rcd 12962, 13047, para. 203 (2000), aff’d in part, rev’d in part, and remanded in part, Texas Office of Public Util. Counsel et al. v. FCC, 265 F.3d 313 (5th Cir. 2001); on remand, Access Charge Reform; Price Cap Performance Review for LECs; Low- Volume Long Distance Users; Federal-State Joint Board on Universal Service, CC Docket Nos. 96-262, 94-1, 99- 249, 96-45, Order on Remand, 18 FCC Rcd 14976 (2003). 130 National Broadband Plan at 147-148. 131 Id. at 147. 132 Verizon Wireless agreed to a five-year phase-out of its competitive ETC high cost support for any properties that it retained after mandated divestitures. Applications of Cellco Partnership d/b/a Verizon Wireless and Atlantis Holdings LLC for Consent to Transfer Control of Licenses, Authorizations, and Spectrum Manager and De Facto Transfer Leasing Arrangements and Petition for Declaratory Ruling that the Transaction is Consistent with Section 310(b)(4) of the Communications Act, WT Docket No. 08-95, File Nos. 0003463892, et al., ITC-T/C-20080613- 00270, et al., ISP-PDR-20080613-00012, Memorandum Opinion and Order and Declaratory Ruling, 23 FCC Rcd 17444, 17529–17532, paras. 192–197 (2008). Similarly, Sprint agreed to a five-year phase-out of its competitive ETC high-cost support as part of its transaction with Clearwire. Applications of Sprint Nextel Corporation and Clearwire Corporation For Consent to Transfer Control of Licenses, Leases and Authorizations, WT Docket No. 08-94, File Nos. 0003462540 et al., Memorandum Opinion and Order and Declaratory Ruling, 23 FCC Rcd 17570, 17612, para. 108 (2008). The National Broadband Plan recommended that this recaptured competitive ETC funding be used to implement the recommendations in the plan. National Broadband Plan at 147. 133 National Broadband Plan at 147-148. Competitive ETC support per line is based on the incumbent telephone company’s support per line. 47 C.F.R. § 54.307. As a consequence, the support a competitive ETC receives is not based on either its costs or the costs of the most efficient technology to support customers in a given area. Federal Communications Commission FCC 10-58 26 subscribers of competitive ETCs if the Commission were to reduce competitive ETC support under the legacy funding mechanisms? How should reductions in legacy high-cost support for all competitive ETCs be coordinated with implementation of Verizon Wireless’s and Sprint’s voluntary commitments to phase-out legacy high-cost support over a five year period? 62. General Proposals. Commenters are invited to submit other proposals to eliminate or reduce funding levels in the legacy high-cost support mechanisms to transition to efficient funding levels in the Connect America Fund. We encourage parties that submit alternative proposals to identify specific rule changes and quantify the impact of such changes. IV. PROCEDURAL MATTERS A. Initial Regulatory Flexibility Analysis 63. As required by the Regulatory Flexibility Act of 1980, as amended, 134 the Commission has prepared an Initial Regulatory Flexibility Analysis (IRFA) for this NPRM, of the possible significant economic impact on a substantial number of small entities by the policies and rules proposed in this further notice. The IRFA is in Appendix A. 135 Written public comments are requested on this IRFA. Comments must be identified as responses to the IRFA and must be filed by the deadlines for comments on the NPRM. The Commission will send a copy of the NPRM, including this IRFA, to the Chief Counsel for Advocacy of the Small Business Administration. 136 In addition, the NPRM and IRFA (or summaries thereof) will be published in the Federal Register. 137 B. Paperwork Reduction Act Analysis 64. This document discusses potential new or revised information collection requirements. The reporting requirements, if any, that might be adopted pursuant to this NPRM are too speculative at this time to request comment from the OMB or interested parties under section 3507(d) of the Paperwork Reduction Act. 138 Therefore, if the Commission determines that reporting is required, it will seek comment from the OMB and interested parties prior to any such requirements taking effect. 139 In addition, pursuant to the Small Business Paperwork Relief Act of 2002, we will seek specific comment on how we might “further reduce the information collection burden for small business concerns with fewer than 25 employees.” 140 Nevertheless, interested parties are encouraged to comment on whether any new or revised information collection is necessary, and if so, how the Commission might minimize the burden of any such collection. C. Ex Parte Presentations 65. These matters shall be treated as a “permit-but-disclose” proceeding in accordance with the Commission’s ex parte rules. 141 Persons making oral ex parte presentations are reminded that memoranda summarizing the presentations must contain summaries of the substance of the presentations 134 5 U.S.C. § 603. 135 See Appendix A. 136 See 5 U.S.C. § 603(a). 137 Id. 138 See 44 U.S.C. § 3507(d). 139 Paperwork Reduction Act of 1995, Pub. L. No. 104-13, 109 Stat. 163 (1995). 140 Small Business Paperwork Relief Act of 2002, Pub. L. No. 107-198, 116 Stat. 729 (2002); 44 U.S.C. § 3506(c)(4). 141 47 C.F.R. §§ 1.1200-1.1216. Federal Communications Commission FCC 10-58 27 and not merely a listing of the subjects discussed. More than a one- or two-sentence description of the views and arguments presented is generally required. 142 Other requirements pertaining to oral and written presentations are set forth in section 1.1206(b) of the Commission’s rules. 143 D. Comment Filing Procedures 66. Pursuant to sections 1.415 and 1.419 of the Commission’s rules, 144 interested parties may file comments and reply comments regarding the NOI and NPRM on or before the dates indicated on the first page of this document. Comments may be filed using: (1) the Commission’s Electronic Comment Filing System (ECFS); (2) the Federal Government’s e-Rulemaking Portal; or (3) by filing paper copies. 145 67. Electronic Filers: Comments may be filed electronically using the Internet by accessing the ECFS: http://fjallfoss.fcc.gov/ecfs/ or the Federal e-Rulemaking Portal: http://www.regulations.gov. 68. Paper Filers: Parties who choose to file by paper must file an original and four copies of each filing. If more than one docket or rulemaking number appears in the caption of this proceeding, filers must submit two additional copies for each additional docket or rulemaking number. 69. Filings can be sent by hand or messenger delivery, by commercial overnight courier, or by first-class or overnight U.S. Postal Service mail. All filings must be addressed to the Commission’s Secretary, Office of the Secretary, Federal Communications Commission. 70. All hand-delivered or messenger-delivered paper filings for the Commission’s Secretary must be delivered to FCC Headquarters at 445 12 th St., SW, Room TW-A325, Washington, DC 20554. All hand deliveries must be held together with rubber bands or fasteners. Any envelopes must be disposed of before entering the building. Commercial overnight mail (other than U.S. Postal Service Express Mail and Priority Mail) must be sent to 9300 East Hampton Drive, Capitol Heights, MD 20743. U.S. Postal Service first-class, Express, and Priority mail must be addressed to 445 12 th Street, S.W., Washington DC 20554. 71. People with Disabilities: To request materials in accessible formats for people with disabilities (Braille, large print, electronic files, audio format), send an e-mail to fcc504@fcc.gov or call the Consumer & Governmental Affairs Bureau at 202-418-0530 (voice), 202-418-0432 (tty). 72. Parties should send a copy of their filings to Charles Tyler, Telecommunications Access Policy Division, Wireline Competition Bureau, Federal Communications Commission, Room 5-A452, 445 12th Street, S.W., Washington, D.C. 20554, or by e-mail to charles.tyler@fcc.gov. Parties shall also serve one copy with the Commission’s copy contractor, Best Copy and Printing, Inc. (BCPI), Portals II, 445 12th Street, S.W., Room CY-B402, Washington, D.C. 20554, (202) 488-5300, or via e-mail to fcc@bcpiweb.com. 73. Documents in this proceeding will be available for public inspection and copying during business hours at the FCC Reference Information Center, Portals II, 445 12th Street S.W., Room CY- A257, Washington, D.C. 20554. The documents may also be purchased from BCPI, telephone (202) 488- 5300, facsimile (202) 488-5563, TTY (202) 488-5562, e-mail fcc@bcpiweb.com. 142 47 C.F.R. § 1.1206(b)(2). 143 47 C.F.R. § 1.1206(b). 144 47 C.F.R. §§ 1.415, 1.419. 145 See Electronic Filing of Documents in Rulemaking Proceedings, GC Docket No. 97-113, Report and Order, 13 FCC Rcd 11322 (1998). Federal Communications Commission FCC 10-58 28 V. ORDERING CLAUSES 74. Accordingly, IT IS ORDERED that, pursuant to the authority contained in sections 1, 2, 4(i), 201-205, 214, 254, and 403 of the Communications Act of 1934, as amended, 47 U.S.C. §§ 151, 152, 154(i), 201-205, 214, 254, and 403 this notice of inquiry IS ADOPTED. 75. IT IS FURTHER ORDERED that, pursuant to the authority contained in sections 1, 2, 4(i), 201-205, 214, 254, and 403 of the Communications Act of 1934, as amended, 47 U.S.C. §§ 151, 152, 154(i), 201-205, 214, 254, and 403, and section 1.411 of the Commission’s rules, 47 C.F.R. § 1.411, this notice of proposed rulemaking IS ADOPTED. 76. IT IS FURTHER ORDERED that the Commission’s Consumer and Governmental Affairs Bureau, Reference Information Center, SHALL SEND a copy of this notice of proposed rulemaking, including the Initial Regulatory Flexibility Analysis, to the Chief Counsel for Advocacy of the Small Business Administration. 77. IT IS FURTHER ORDERED, pursuant to sections 1.4(b)(1) and 1.103(a) of the Commission’s rules, 47 C.F.R. §§ 1.4(b)(1), 1.103(a), that this notice of notice of proposed rulemaking SHALL BE EFFECTIVE on the date of publication in the Federal Register. FEDERAL COMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION Marlene H. Dortch Secretary Federal Communications Commission FCC 10-58 29 er. APPENDIX A Initial Regulatory Flexibility Analysis 1. As required by the Regulatory Flexibility Act (“RFA”), 1 the Commission prepared this Initial Regulatory Flexibility Analysis (“IRFA”) of the possible significant economic impact on small entities by the policies and rules proposed in this Notice of Proposed Rulemaking (NPRM). The Commission requests written public comments on this IRFA. Comments must be identified as responses to the IRFA and must be filed on or before the dates indicated on the first page of this NPRM. The Commission will send a copy of the NPRM, including this IRFA, to the Chief Counsel for Advocacy of the Small Business Administration (SBA). 2 In addition, the NPRM and IRFA (or summaries thereof) will be published in the Federal Regist 3 I. Need for, and Objectives of, the Notice: 2. On March 16, 2010, the Commission released a Joint Statement on Broadband stating that “[t]he nearly $9 billion Universal Service Fund (USF) and the intercarrier compensation (ICC) system should be comprehensively reformed to increase accountability and efficiency, encourage targeted investment in broadband infrastructure, and emphasize the importance of broadband to the future of these programs.” 4 On the same day, the Commission delivered to Congress a National Broadband Plan recommending that the Commission adopt cost-cutting measures for existing voice support and create a Connect America Fund (CAF), without increasing the overall size of the Fund, to support the provision of broadband communications in areas that would be unserved without such support or that depend on universal service support for the maintenance of existing broadband service. 5 3. The National Broadband Plan recommends that the Commission take steps to manage the universal service fund so that its total size remains close to its current level (in 2010 dollars) to minimize the burden of increasing universal service contributions on consumers. 6 The NPRM seeks comment on specific common-sense reforms to contain growth in the legacy high-cost support mechanisms and identify savings that can be shifted toward broadband. Specifically, the NPRM seeks comment on capping legacy high-cost support provided to incumbent telephone companies at 2010 levels; 7 shifting rate-of-return carriers to incentive regulation and converting interstate common line support to a frozen amount per line; 8 eliminating interstate access support; 9 and eliminating high-cost support for competitive eligible telecommunications carriers. 10 1 5 U.S.C. § 603. The RFA, 5 U.S.C. §§ 601-612, has been amended by the Small Business Regulatory Enforcement Fairness Act of 1996 (SBREFA), Public Law No. 104-121, Title II, 110 Stat. 857 (1996). 2 5 U.S.C. § 603(a). 3 Id. 4 Joint Statement on Broadband, GN Docket No. 10-66, Joint Statement on Broadband, FCC 10-42 (rel. Mar.16, 2010) at 2. 5 Federal Communications Commission, Connecting America: The National Broadband Plan, (rel. Mar. 16, 2010) (National Broadband Plan) at 144. 6 See id. at 149. 7 See NPRM, paras. 51-52. 8 See id., paras. 55-56. 9 See id., paras. 57-58. 10 See id., paras. 60-61. Federal Communications Commission FCC 10-58 30 II. Legal Basis: 4. This legal basis for any action that may be taken pursuant to the NPRM is contained in sections 1, 2, 4(i), 201-205, 214, 254, and 403 of the Communications Act of 1934, as amended, 47 U.S.C. §§ 151, 152, 154(i), 201-205, 214, 254, and 403, and section 1.411 of the Commission’s rules, 47 C.F.R. § 1.411. III. Description and Estimate of the Number of Small Entities to which the Rules Will Apply: 5. The RFA directs agencies to provide a description of, and where feasible, an estimate of the number of small entities that may be affected by the proposed rules and policies, if adopted. 11 The RFA generally defines the term “small entity” as having the same meaning as the terms “small business,” “small organization,” and “small governmental jurisdiction.” 12 In addition, the term “small business” has the same meaning as the term “small business concern” under the Small Business Act. 13 A “small business concern” is one which: (1) is independently owned and operated; (2) is not dominant in its field of operation; and (3) satisfies any additional criteria established by the SBA. 14 6. Small Businesses. Nationwide, there are a total of approximately 29.6 million small businesses, according to the SBA. 15 7. Small Organizations. Nationwide, as of 2002, there are approximately 1.6 million small organizations. 16 A “small organization” is generally “any not-for-profit enterprise which is independently owned and operated and is not dominant in its field.” 17 8. Small Governmental Jurisdictions. The term “small governmental jurisdiction” is defined generally as “governments of cities, towns, townships, villages, school districts, or special districts, with a population of less than fifty thousand.” 18 Census Bureau data for 2002 indicate that there were 87,525 local governmental jurisdictions in the United States. 19 We estimate that, of this total, 84,377 entities were “small governmental jurisdictions.” 20 Thus, we estimate that most governmental jurisdictions are small. 9. We have included small incumbent local exchange carriers in this present RFA analysis. As noted above, a “small business” under the RFA is one that, inter alia, meets the pertinent small 11 5 U.S.C. § 603(b)(3). 12 5 U.S.C. § 601(6). 13 5 U.S.C. § 601(3) (incorporating by reference the definition of “small-business concern” in the Small Business Act, 15 U.S.C. § 632). Pursuant to 5 U.S.C. § 601(3), the statutory definition of a small business applies “unless an agency, after consultation with the Office of Advocacy of the Small Business Administration and after opportunity for public comment, establishes one or more definitions of such term which are appropriate to the activities of the agency and publishes such definition(s) in the Federal Register.” 14 15 U.S.C. § 632. 15 See SBA, Office of Advocacy, “Frequently Asked Questions,” http://web.sba.gov/faqs (accessed Apr. 2010). 16 Independent Sector, The New Nonprofit Almanac & Desk Reference (2002). 17 5 U.S.C. § 601(4). 18 5 U.S.C. § 601(5). 19 U.S. Census Bureau, Statistical Abstract of the United States: 2006, Section 8, p. 272, Table 415. 20 We assume that the villages, school districts, and special districts are small, and total 48,558. See U.S. Census Bureau, Statistical Abstract of the United States: 2006, section 8, p. 273, Table 417. For 2002, Census Bureau data indicate that the total number of county, municipal, and township governments nationwide was 38,967, of which 35,819 were small. Id. Federal Communications Commission FCC 10-58 31 d business size standard (e.g., a telephone communications business having 1,500 or fewer employees), and “is not dominant in its field of operation.” 21 The SBA’s Office of Advocacy contends that, for RFA purposes, small incumbent local exchange carriers are not dominant in their field of operation because any such dominance is not “national” in scope. 22 We have therefore included small incumbent local exchange carriers in this RFA analysis, although we emphasize that this RFA action has no effect on Commission analyses and determinations in other, non-RFA contexts. 10. Incumbent Local Exchange Carriers (“ILECs”). Neither the Commission nor the SBA has developed a small business size standard specifically for incumbent local exchange services. The appropriate size standard under SBA rules is for the category Wired Telecommunications Carriers. Under that size standard, such a business is small if it has 1,500 or fewer employees. 23 According to Commission data, 24 1,311 carriers have reported that they are engaged in the provision of incumbent local exchange services. Of these 1,311 carriers, an estimated 1,024 have 1,500 or fewer employees and 287 have more than 1,500 employees. Consequently, the Commission estimates that most providers of incumbent local exchange service are small businesses that may be affected by our proposed action. 11. Competitive Local Exchange Carriers (“CLECs”), Competitive Access Providers (“CAPs”), “Shared-Tenant Service Providers,” and “Other Local Service Providers.” Neither the Commission nor the SBA has developed a small business size standard specifically for these service providers. The appropriate size standard under SBA rules is for the category Wired Telecommunications Carriers. Under that size standard, such a business is small if it has 1,500 or fewer employees. 25 According to Commission data, 26 1005 carriers have reported that they are engaged in the provision of either competitive access provider services or competitive local exchange carrier services. Of these 1005 carriers, an estimated 918 have 1,500 or fewer employees and 87 have more than 1,500 employees. In addition, 16 carriers have reported that they are “Shared-Tenant Service Providers,” and all 16 are estimated to have 1,500 or fewer employees. In addition, 89 carriers have reported that they are “Other Local Service Providers.” Of the 89, all have 1,500 or fewer employees. Consequently, the Commission estimates that most providers of competitive local exchange service, competitive access providers, “Shared-Tenant Service Providers,” and “Other Local Service Providers” are small entities that may be affected by our proposed action. 12. Local Resellers. The SBA has developed a small business size standard for the category of Telecommunications Resellers. Under that size standard, such a business is small if it has 1,500 or fewer employees. 27 According to Commission data, 28 151 carriers have reported that they are engaged in the provision of local resale services. Of these, an estimated 149 have 1,500 or fewer employees an 21 15 U.S. C. § 632. 22 Letter from Jere W. Glover, Chief Counsel for Advocacy, SBA, to William E. Kennard, Chairman, FCC (May 27, 1999). The Small Business Act contains a definition of “small-business concern,” which the RFA incorporates into its own definition of “small business.” See 15 U.S.C. § 632(a) (“Small Business Act”); 5 U.S.C. § 601(3) (“RFA”). SBA regulations interpret “small business concern” to include the concept of dominance on a national basis. See 13 C.F.R. § 121.102(b). 23 13 C.F.R. § 121.201, North American Industry Classification System (NAICS) code 517110. 24 FCC, Wireline Competition Bureau, Industry Analysis and Technology Division, “Trends in Telephone Service” at Table 5.3, Page 5-5 (Aug. 2008) (“Trends in Telephone Service”). This source uses data that are current as of November 1, 2006. 25 13 C.F.R. § 121.201, NAICS code 517110. 26 “Trends in Telephone Service” at Table 5.3. 27 13 C.F.R. § 121.201, NAICS code 517310. 28 “Trends in Telephone Service” at Table 5.3. Federal Communications Commission FCC 10-58 32 8 oposed action. uge . two have more than 1,500 employees. Consequently, the Commission estimates that the majority of local resellers are small entities that may be affected by our proposed action. 13. Toll Resellers. The SBA has developed a small business size standard for the category of Telecommunications Resellers. Under that size standard, such a business is small if it has 1,500 or fewer employees. 29 According to Commission data, 30 815 carriers have reported that they are engaged in the provision of toll resale services. Of these, an estimated 787 have 1,500 or fewer employees and 2 have more than 1,500 employees. Consequently, the Commission estimates that the majority of toll resellers are small entities that may be affected by our proposed action. 14. Interexchange Carriers (“IXCs”). Neither the Commission nor the SBA has developed a small business size standard specifically for providers of interexchange services. The appropriate size standard under SBA rules is for the category Wired Telecommunications Carriers. Under that size standard, such a business is small if it has 1,500 or fewer employees. 31 According to Commission data, 32 300 carriers have reported that they are engaged in the provision of interexchange service. Of these, an estimated 268 have 1,500 or fewer employees and 32 have more than 1,500 employees. Consequently, the Commission estimates that the majority of IXCs are small entities that may be affected by our pr 15. Satellite Telecommunications and All Other Telecommunications. These two economic census categories address the satellite industry. The first category has a small business size standard of $15 million or less in average annual receipts, under SBA rules. 33 The second has a size standard of $25 million or less in annual receipts. 34 The most current Census Bureau data in this context, however, are from the (last) economic census of 2002, and we will use those figures to ga the prevalence of small businesses in these categories 35 16. The category of Satellite Telecommunications “comprises establishments primarily engaged in providing telecommunications services to other establishments in the telecommunications and broadcasting industries by forwarding and receiving communications signals via a system of satellites or reselling satellite telecommunications.” 36 For this category, Census Bureau data for 2002 show that there were a total of 371 firms that operated for the entire year. 37 Of this total, 307 firms had annual receipts of under $10 million, and 26 firms had receipts of $10 million to $24,999,999. 38 Consequently, we estimate that the majority of Satellite Telecommunications firms are small entities that might be affected by our action. 17. The second category of All Other Telecommunications comprises, inter alia, “establishments primarily engaged in providing specialized telecommunications services, such as satellite tracking, communications telemetry, and radar station operation. This industry also includes 29 13 C.F.R. § 121.201, NAICS code 517310. 30 “Trends in Telephone Service” at Table 5.3. 31 13 C.F.R. § 121.201, NAICS code 517110. 32 “Trends in Telephone Service” at Table 5.3. 33 13 C.F.R. § 121.201, NAICS code 517410. 34 13 C.F.R. § 121.201, NAICS code 517919. 35 13 C.F.R. § 121.201, NAICS codes 517410 and 517910 (2002). 36 U.S. Census Bureau, 2007 NAICS Definitions, “517410 Satellite Telecommunications”; http://www.census.gov/naics/2007/def/ND517410.HTM. 37 U.S. Census Bureau, 2002 Economic Census, Subject Series: Information, “Establishment and Firm Size (Including Legal Form of Organization),” Table 4, NAICS code 517410 (issued Nov. 2005). 38 Id. An additional 38 firms had annual receipts of $25 million or more. Federal Communications Commission FCC 10-58 33 eless establishments primarily engaged in providing satellite terminal stations and associated facilities connected with one or more terrestrial systems and capable of transmitting telecommunications to, and receiving telecommunications from, satellite systems.” 39 For this category, Census Bureau data for 2002 show that there were a total of 332 firms that operated for the entire year. 40 Of this total, 303 firms had annual receipts of under $10 million and 15 firms had annual receipts of $10 million to $24,999,999. 41 Consequently, we estimate that the majority of All Other Telecommunications firms are small entities that might be affected by our action. 18. Wireless Telecommunications Carriers (except Satellite). Since 2007, the Census Bureau has placed wireless firms within this new, broad, economic census category. 42 Prior to that time, such firms were within the now-superseded categories of “Paging” and “Cellular and Other Wireless Telecommunications.” 43 Under the present and prior categories, the SBA has deemed a wireless business to be small if it has 1,500 or fewer employees. 44 Because Census Bureau data are not yet available for the new category, we will estimate small business prevalence using the prior categories and associated data. For the category of Paging, data for 2002 show that there were 807 firms that operated for the entire year. 45 Of this total, 804 firms had employment of 999 or fewer employees, and three firms had employment of 1,000 employees or more. 46 For the category of Cellular and Other Wir Telecommunications, data for 2002 show that there were 1,397 firms that operated for the entire year. 47 Of this total, 1,378 firms had employment of 999 or fewer employees, and 19 firms had employment of 1,000 employees or more. 48 Thus, we estimate that the majority of wireless firms are small. 19. 2.3 GHz Wireless Communications Services. This service can be used for fixed, mobile, radiolocation, and digital audio broadcasting satellite uses. The Commission defined “small business” for the wireless communications services (“WCS”) auction as an entity with average gross revenues of $40 million for each of the three preceding years, and a “very small business” as an entity with average gross revenues of $15 million for each of the three preceding years. 49 The SBA has 39 U.S. Census Bureau, 2007 NAICS Definitions, “517919 All Other Telecommunications”; http://www.census.gov/naics/2007/def/ND517919.HTM#N517919. 40 U.S. Census Bureau, 2002 Economic Census, Subject Series: Information, “Establishment and Firm Size (Including Legal Form of Organization),” Table 4, NAICS code 517910 (issued Nov. 2005). 41 Id. An additional 14 firms had annual receipts of $25 million or more. 42 U.S. Census Bureau, 2007 NAICS Definitions, “517210 Wireless Telecommunications Categories (Except Satellite)”; http://www.census.gov/naics/2007/def/ND517210.HTM#N517210. 43 U.S. Census Bureau, 2002 NAICS Definitions, “517211 Paging”; http://www.census.gov/epcd/naics02/def/NDEF517.HTM.; U.S. Census Bureau, 2002 NAICS Definitions, “517212 Cellular and Other Wireless Telecommunications”; http://www.census.gov/epcd/naics02/def/NDEF517.HTM. 44 13 C.F.R. § 121.201, NAICS code 517210 (2007 NAICS). The now-superseded, pre-2007 C.F.R. citations were 13 C.F.R. § 121.201, NAICS codes 517211 and 517212 (referring to the 2002 NAICS). 45 U.S. Census Bureau, 2002 Economic Census, Subject Series: Information, “Establishment and Firm Size (Including Legal Form of Organization,” Table 5, NAICS code 517211 (issued Nov. 2005). 46 Id. The census data do not provide a more precise estimate of the number of firms that have employment of 1,500 or fewer employees; the largest category provided is for firms with “1000 employees or more.” 47 U.S. Census Bureau, 2002 Economic Census, Subject Series: Information, “Establishment and Firm Size (Including Legal Form of Organization,” Table 5, NAICS code 517212 (issued Nov. 2005). 48 Id. The census data do not provide a more precise estimate of the number of firms that have employment of 1,500 or fewer employees; the largest category provided is for firms with “1000 employees or more.” 49 Amendment of the Commission’s Rules to Establish Part 27, the Wireless Communications Service (WCS), Report and Order, 12 FCC Rcd 10785, 10879, para. 194 (1997). Federal Communications Commission FCC 10-58 34 approved these definitions. 50 The Commission auctioned geographic area licenses in the WCS service. In the auction, which was conducted in 1997, there were seven bidders that won 31 licenses that qualified as very small business entities, and one bidder that won one license that qualified as a small business entity. 20. 1670-1675 MHz Services. An auction for one license in the 1670-1675 MHz band was conducted in 2003. One license was awarded. The winning bidder was not a small entity. 21. Wireless Telephony. Wireless telephony includes cellular, personal communications services, and specialized mobile radio telephony carriers. As noted, the SBA has developed a small business size standard for Wireless Telecommunications Carriers (except Satellite). 51 Under the SBA small business size standard, a business is small if it has 1,500 or fewer employees. 52 According to Trends in Telephone Service data, 434 carriers reported that they were engaged in wireless telephony. 53 Of these, an estimated 222 have 1,500 or fewer employees and 212 have more than 1,500 employees. 54 We have estimated that 222 of these are small under the SBA small business size standard. 22. Broadband Personal Communications Service. The broadband personal communications services (“PCS”) spectrum is divided into six frequency blocks designated A through F, and the Commission has held auctions for each block. The Commission has created a small business size standard for Blocks C and F as an entity that has average gross revenues of less than $40 million in the three previous calendar years. 55 For Block F, an additional small business size standard for “very small business” was added and is defined as an entity that, together with its affiliates, has average gross revenues of not more than $15 million for the preceding three calendar years. 56 These small business size standards, in the context of broadband PCS auctions, have been approved by the SBA. 57 No small businesses within the SBA-approved small business size standards bid successfully for licenses in Blocks A and B. There were 90 winning bidders that qualified as small entities in the Block C auctions. A total of 93 “small” and “very small” business bidders won approximately 40 percent of the 1,479 licenses for Blocks D, E, and F. 58 In 1999, the Commission reauctioned 155 C, D, E, and F Block licenses; there were 113 small business winning bidders. 59 23. In 2001, the Commission completed the auction of 422 C and F Broadband PCS licenses in Auction 35. Of the 35 winning bidders in this auction, 29 qualified as “small” or “very small” businesses. 60 Subsequent events, concerning Auction 35, including judicial and agency determinations, resulted in a total of 163 C and F Block licenses being available for grant. In 2005, the Commission completed an auction of 188 C block licenses and 21 F block licenses in Auction 58. There were 24 50 See Alvarez Letter 1998. 51 13 C.F.R. § 121.201, NAICS code 517210. 52 Id. 53 “Trends in Telephone Service” at Table 5.3. 54 “Trends in Telephone Service” at Table 5.3. 55 See Amendment of Parts 20 and 24 of the Commission’s Rules – Broadband PCS Competitive Bidding and the Commercial Mobile Radio Service Spectrum Cap, Report and Order, 11 FCC Rcd 7824, 7850-7852, paras. 57-60 (1996) (“PCS Report and Order”); see also 47 C.F.R. § 24.720(b). 56 See PCS Report and Order, 11 FCC Rcd at 7852, para. 60. 57 See Alvarez Letter 1998. 58 FCC News, “Broadband PCS, D, E and F Block Auction Closes,” No. 71744 (rel. Jan. 14, 1997). 59 See “C, D, E, and F Block Broadband PCS Auction Closes,” Public Notice, 14 FCC Rcd 6688 (WTB 1999). 60 See “C and F Block Broadband PCS Auction Closes; Winning Bidders Announced,” Public Notice, 16 FCC Rcd 2339 (2001). Federal Communications Commission FCC 10-58 35 S-1 s”) million e licenses. ch s small business has average gross revenues that are not more than $3 million for the preceding three years. The SBA winning bidders for 217 licenses. 61 Of the 24 winning bidders, 16 claimed small business status and won 156 licenses. In 2007, the Commission completed an auction of 33 licenses in the A, C, and F Blocks in Auction 71. 62 Of the 14 winning bidders, six were designated entities. 63 In 2008, the Commission completed an auction of 20 Broadband PCS licenses in the C, D, E and F block licenses in 64 Auction 78. 24. Advanced Wireless Services. In 2008, the Commission conducted the auction of Advanced Wireless Services (“AWS”) licenses. 65 This auction, which as designated as Auction 78, offered 35 licenses in the AWS 1710-1755 MHz and 2110-2155 MHz bands (“AWS-1”). The AW licenses were licenses for which there were no winning bids in Auction 66. That same year, the Commission completed Auction 78. A bidder with attributed average annual gross revenues that exceeded $15 million and did not exceed $40 million for the preceding three years (“small busines received a 15 percent discount on its winning bid. A bidder with attributed average annual gross revenues that did not exceed $15 million for the preceding three years (“very small business”) received a 25 percent discount on its winning bid. A bidder that had combined total assets of less than $500 and combined gross revenues of less than $125 million in each of the last two years qualified for entrepreneur status. 66 Four winning bidders that identified themselves as very small businesses won 17 licenses. 67 Three of the winning bidders that identified themselves as a small business won fiv Additionally, one other winning bidder that qualified for entrepreneur status won 2 licenses. 25. 700 MHz Band Licenses. The Commission previously adopted criteria for defining three groups of small businesses for purposes of determining their eligibility for special provisions su as bidding credits. 68 The Commission defined a “small business” as an entity that, together with it affiliates and controlling principals, has average gross revenues not exceeding $40 million for the preceding three years. 69 A “very small business” is defined as an entity that, together with its affiliates and controlling principals, has average gross revenues that are not more than $15 million for the preceding three years. 70 Additionally, the lower 700 MHz Service had a third category of status for Metropolitan/Rural Service Area (“MSA/RSA”) licenses. The third category is “entrepreneur,” which is defined as an entity that, together with its affiliates and controlling principals, 71 61 See “Broadband PCS Spectrum Auction Closes; Winning Bidders Announced for Auction No. 58,” Public Notice, 20 FCC Rcd 3703 (2005). 62 See “Auction of Broadband PCS Spectrum Licenses Closes; Winning Bidders Announced for Auction No. 71,” Public Notice, 22 FCC Rcd 9247 (2007). 63 Id. 64 See Auction of AWS-1 and Broadband PCS Licenses Rescheduled For August 13, 3008, Notice of Filing Requirements, Minimum Opening Bids, Upfront Payments and Other Procedures For Auction 78, Public Notice, 23 FCC Rcd 7496 (2008) (“AWS-1 and Broadband PCS Procedures Public Notice”). 65 See AWS-1 and Broadband PCS Procedures Public Notice, 23 FCC Rcd 7496. Auction 78 also included an auction of Broadband PCS licenses. 66 Id. at 23 FCC Rcd at 7521-22. 67 See “Auction of AWS-1 and Broadband PCS Licenses Closes, Winning Bidders Announced for Auction 78, Down Payments Due September 9, 2008, FCC Forms 601 and 602 Due September 9, 2008, Final Payments Due September 23, 2008, Ten-Day Petition to Deny Period”, Public Notice, 23 FCC Rcd 12749-65 (2008). 68 See Reallocation and Service Rules for the 698-746 MHz Spectrum Band (Television Channels 52-59), Report and Order, 17 FCC Rcd 1022 (2002) (“Channels 52-59 Report and Order”). 69 See Channels 52-59 Report and Order, 17 FCC Rcd at 1087-88, ¶ 172. 70 See id. 71 See id, 17 FCC Rcd at 1088, ¶ 173. Federal Communications Commission FCC 10-58 36 approved these small size standards. 72 The Commission conducted an auction in 2002 of 740 licenses (one license in each of the 734 MSAs/RSAs and one license in each of the six Economic Area Groupings (EAGs)). Of the 740 licenses available for auction, 484 licenses were sold to 102 winning bidders. Seventy-two of the winning bidders claimed small business, very small business or entrepreneur status and won a total of 329 licenses. 73 The Commission conducted a second auction in 2003 that included 256 licenses: 5 EAG licenses and 476 Cellular Market Area licenses. 74 Seventeen winning bidders claimed small or very small business status and won 60 licenses, and nine winning bidders claimed entrepreneur status and won 154 licenses. 75 In 2005, the Commission completed an auction of 5 licenses in the lower 700 MHz band (Auction 60). There were three winning bidders for five licenses. All three winning bidders claimed small business status. 26. In 2007, the Commission adopted the 700 MHz Second Report and Order. 76 The Order revised the band plan for the commercial (including Guard Band) and public safety spectrum, adopted services rules, including stringent build-out requirements, an open platform requirement on the C Block, and a requirement on the D Block licensee to construct and operate a nationwide, interoperable wireless broadband network for public safety users. In 2008, the Commission commenced Auction 73 which offered all available, commercial 700 MHz Band licenses (1,099 licenses) for bidding using the Commission’s standard simultaneous multiple-round (“SMR”) auction format for the A, B, D, and E block licenses and an SMR auction design with hierarchical package bidding (“HPB”) for the C Block licenses. Later in 2008, the Commission concluded Auction 73. 77 A bidder with attributed average annual gross revenues that did not exceed $15 million for the preceding three years (very small business) qualified for a 25 percent discount on its winning bids. A bidder with attributed average annual gross revenues that exceeded $15 million, but did not exceed $40 million for the preceding three years, qualified for a 15 percent discount on its winning bids. There were 36 winning bidders (who won 330 of the 1,090 licenses won) that identified themselves as very small businesses. There were 20 winning bidders that identified themselves as a small business that won 49 of the 1,090 licenses won. 78 The provisionally winning bids for the A, B, C, and E Block licenses exceeded the aggregate reserve prices for those blocks. However, the provisionally winning bid for the D Block license did not meet the applicable reserve price and thus did not become a winning bid. 79 72 See Letter from Aida Alvarez, Administrator, SBA, to Thomas Sugrue, Chief, WTB, FCC (Aug. 10, 1999) (“Alvarez Letter 1999”). 73 See “Lower 700 MHz Band Auction Closes,” Public Notice, 17 FCC Rcd 17272 (WTB 2002). 74 See “Lower 700 MHz Band Auction Closes,” Public Notice, 18 FCC Rcd 11873 (WTB 2003). 75 See id. 76 Service Rules for the 698-746, 747-762 and 777-792 MHz Band, WT Docket No. 06-150, Revision of the Commission’s Rules to Ensure Compatibility with Enhanced 911 Emergency Calling Systems, CC Docket No. 94- 102, Section 68.4(a) of the Commission’s Rules Governing Hearing Aid-Compatible Telephone, WT Docket No. 01- 309, Biennial Regulatory Review – Amendment of Parts 1, 22, 24, 27, and 90 to Streamline and Harmonize Various Rules Affecting Wireless Radio Services, WT Docket No. 03-264, Former Nextel Communications, Inc. Upper700 MHz Guard Band Licenses and Revisions to Part 27 of the Commission’s Rules, WT Docket No. 06-169, Implementing a Nationwide, Broadband Interoperable Public Safety Network in the 700 MHz Band, PS Docket No. 06-229, Development of Operational, Technical and Spectrum Requirements for Meeting Federal, State, and Local Public Safety Communications Requirements Through the Year 2010, WT Docket No. 96-86, Second Report and Order, FCC 07-132 (2007) (“700 MHz Second Report and Order”), 22 FCC Rcd 15289 (2007). 77 Auction of 700 MHz Band Licenses Closes, Winning Bidders Announced for Auction 73, Down Payments Due April 3, 2008, FCC Forms 601 and 602 April 3, 2008, Final Payment Due April 17, 2008, Ten-Day Petition to Deny Period, Public Notice, 23 FCC Rcd 4572 (2008). 78 Id. 23 FCC Rcd at 4572-73. 79 Id. Federal Communications Commission FCC 10-58 37 uard 27. 700 MHz Guard Band Licenses. In the 700 MHz Guard Band Order, the Commission adopted size standards for “small businesses” and “very small businesses” for purposes of determining their eligibility for special provisions such as bidding credits and installment payments. 80 A small business in this service is an entity that, together with its affiliates and controlling principals, has average gross revenues not exceeding $40 million for the preceding three years. 81 Additionally, a very small business is an entity that, together with its affiliates and controlling principals, has average gross revenues that are not more than $15 million for the preceding three years. 82 SBA approval of these definitions is not required. 83 In 2000, the Commission conducted an auction of 52 Major Economic Area (“MEA”) licenses. 84 Of the 104 licenses auctioned, 96 licenses were sold to nine bidders. Five of these bidders were small businesses that won a total of 26 licenses. A second auction of 700 MHz G Band licenses commenced and closed in 2001. All eight of the licenses auctioned were sold to three bidders. One of these bidders was a small business that won a total of two licenses. 85 28. Specialized Mobile Radio. The Commission awards “small entity” bidding credits in auctions for Specialized Mobile Radio (SMR) geographic area licenses in the 800 MHz and 900 MHz bands to firms that had revenues of no more than $15 million in each of the three previous calendar years. 86 The Commission awards “very small entity” bidding credits to firms that had revenues of no more than $3 million in each of the three previous calendar years. 87 The SBA has approved these small business size standards for the 900 MHz Service. 88 The Commission has held auctions for geographic area licenses in the 800 MHz and 900 MHz bands. The 900 MHz SMR auction was completed in 1996. Sixty bidders claiming that they qualified as small businesses under the $15 million size standard won 263 geographic area licenses in the 900 MHz SMR band. The 800 MHz SMR auction for the upper 200 channels was conducted in 1997. Ten bidders claiming that they qualified as small businesses under the $15 million size standard won 38 geographic area licenses for the upper 200 channels in the 800 MHz SMR band. 89 A second auction for the 800 MHz band was conducted in 2002 and included 23 BEA licenses. One bidder claiming small business status won five licenses. 90 29. The auction of the 1,053 800 MHz SMR geographic area licenses for the General Category channels was conducted in 2000. Eleven bidders won 108 geographic area licenses for the General Category channels in the 800 MHz SMR band qualified as small businesses under the $15 80 See Service Rules for the 746-764 MHz Bands, and Revisions to Part 27 of the Commission’s Rules, Second Report and Order, 15 FCC Rcd 5299 (2000) (“746-764 MHz Band Second Report and Order”). 81 See 746-764 MHz Band Second Report and Order, 15 FCC Rcd at 5343, para. 108. 82 See id. 83 See id., 15 FCC Rcd 5299, 5343, para. 108 n.246 (for the 746-764 MHz and 776-794 MHz bands, the Commission is exempt from 15 U.S.C. § 632, which requires Federal agencies to obtain SBA approval before adopting small business size standards). 84 See “700 MHz Guard Bands Auction Closes: Winning Bidders Announced,” Public Notice, 15 FCC Rcd 18026 (2000). 85 See “700 MHz Guard Bands Auction Closes: Winning Bidders Announced,” Public Notice, 16 FCC Rcd 4590 (WTB 2001). 86 47 C.F.R. § 90.814(b)(1). 87 47 C.F.R. § 90.814(b)(1). 88 See Alvarez Letter 1999. 89 See “Correction to Public Notice DA 96-586 ‘FCC Announces Winning Bidders in the Auction of 1020 Licenses to Provide 900 MHz SMR in Major Trading Areas,’” Public Notice, 18 FCC Rcd 18367 (WTB 1996). 90 See “Multi-Radio Service Auction Closes,” Public Notice, 17 FCC Rcd 1446 (WTB 2002). Federal Communications Commission FCC 10-58 38 million size standard. 91 In an auction completed in 2000, a total of 2,800 Economic Area licenses in the lower 80 channels of the 800 MHz SMR service were awarded. 92 Of the 22 winning bidders, 19 claimed small business status and won 129 licenses. Thus, combining all three auctions, 40 winning bidders for geographic licenses in the 800 MHz SMR band claimed status as small business. 30. In addition, there are numerous incumbent site-by-site SMR licensees and licensees with extended implementation authorizations in the 800 and 900 MHz bands. We do not know how many firms provide 800 MHz or 900 MHz geographic area SMR pursuant to extended implementation authorizations, nor how many of these providers have annual revenues of no more than $15 million. One firm has over $15 million in revenues. In addition, we do not know how many of these firms have 1500 or fewer employees. 93 We assume, for purposes of this analysis, that all of the remaining existing extended implementation authorizations are held by small entities, as that small business size standard is approved by the SBA. 31. Cellular Radiotelephone Service. Auction 77 was held to resolve one group of mutually exclusive applications for Cellular Radiotelephone Service licenses for unserved areas in New Mexico. 94 Bidding credits for designated entities were not available in Auction 77. 95 In 2008, the Commission completed the closed auction of one unserved service area in the Cellular Radiotelephone Service, designated as Auction 77. Auction 77 concluded with one provisionally winning bid for the unserved area totaling $25,002. 96 32. Private Land Mobile Radio (“PLMR”). PLMR systems serve an essential role in a range of industrial, business, land transportation, and public safety activities. These radios are used by companies of all sizes operating in all U.S. business categories, and are often used in support of the licensee’s primary (non-telecommunications) business operations. For the purpose of determining whether a licensee of a PLMR system is a small business as defined by the SBA, we use the broad census category, Wireless Telecommunications Carriers (except Satellite). This definition provides that a small entity is any such entity employing no more than 1,500 persons. 97 The Commission does not require PLMR licensees to disclose information about number of employees, so the Commission does not have information that could be used to determine how many PLMR licensees constitute small entities under this definition. We note that PLMR licensees generally use the licensed facilities in support of other business activities, and therefore, it would also be helpful to assess PLMR licensees under the standards applied to the particular industry subsector to which the licensee belongs. 98 33. As of March 2010, there were 424,162 PLMR licensees operating 921,909 transmitters in the PLMR bands below 512 MHz. We note that any entity engaged in a commercial activity is eligible 91 See “800 MHz Specialized Mobile Radio (SMR) Service General Category (851-854 MHz) and Upper Band (861-865 MHz) Auction Closes; Winning Bidders Announced,” Public Notice, 15 FCC Rcd 17162 (2000). 92 See, “800 MHz SMR Service Lower 80 Channels Auction Closes; Winning Bidders Announced,” Public Notice, 16 FCC Rcd 1736 (2000). 93 See generally 13 C.F.R. § 121.201, NAICS code 517210. 94 See Closed Auction of Licenses for Cellular Unserved Service Area Scheduled for June 17, 2008, Notice and Filing Requirements, Minimum Opening Bids, Upfront Payments, and Other Procedures for Auction 77, Public Notice, 23 FCC Rcd 6670 (2008). 95 Id. at 6685. 96 See Auction of Cellular Unserved Service Area License Closes, Winning Bidder Announced for Auction 77, Down Payment due July 2, 2008, Final Payment due July 17, 2008, Public Notice, 23 FCC Rcd 9501 (2008). 97 See 13 C.F.R. § 121.201, NAICS code 517210. 98 See generally 13 C.F.R. § 121.201. Federal Communications Commission FCC 10-58 39 to hold a PLMR license, and that any revised rules in this context could therefore potentially impact small entities covering a great variety of industries. 34. Fixed Microwave Services. Fixed microwave services include common carrier, 99 private operational-fixed, 100 and broadcast auxiliary radio services. 101 At present, there are approximately 22,015 common carrier fixed licensees and 61,670 private operational-fixed licensees and broadcast auxiliary radio licensees in the microwave services. The Commission has not created a size standard for a small business specifically with respect to fixed microwave services. For purposes of this analysis, the Commission uses the SBA small business size standard for the category Wireless Telecommunications Carriers (except Satellite), which is 1,500 or fewer employees. 102 The Commission does not have data specifying the number of these licensees that have no more than 1,500 employees, and thus are unable at this time to estimate with greater precision the number of fixed microwave service licensees that would qualify as small business concerns under the SBA’s small business size standard. Consequently, the Commission estimates that there are 22,015 or fewer common carrier fixed licensees and 61,670 or fewer private operational-fixed licensees and broadcast auxiliary radio licensees in the microwave services that may be small and may be affected by the rules and policies proposed herein. We note, however, that the common carrier microwave fixed licensee category includes some large entities. 35. 39 GHz Service. The Commission created a special small business size standard for 39 GHz licenses – an entity that has average gross revenues of $40 million or less in the three previous calendar years. 103 An additional size standard for “very small business” is: an entity that, together with affiliates, has average gross revenues of not more than $15 million for the preceding three calendar years. 104 The SBA has approved these small business size standards. 105 The auction of the 2,173, 39 GHz licenses, began and closed in 2000. The 18 bidders who claimed small business status won 849 licenses. 36. Local Multipoint Distribution Service. Local Multipoint Distribution Service (“LMDS”) is a fixed broadband point-to-multipoint microwave service that provides for two-way video telecommunications. 106 The auction of the 986 LMDS licenses began and closed in 1998. The (continued….) 99 See 47 C.F.R. §§ 101 et seq. for common carrier fixed microwave services (except Multipoint Distribution Service). 100 Persons eligible under parts 80 and 90 of the Commission’s Rules can use Private Operational-Fixed Microwave services. See 47 C.F.R. Parts 80 and 90. Stations in this service are called operational-fixed to distinguish them from common carrier and public fixed stations. Only the licensee may use the operational-fixed station, and only for communications related to the licensee’s commercial, industrial, or safety operations. 101 Auxiliary Microwave Service is governed by Part 74 of Title 47 of the Commission’s Rules. See 47 C.F.R. Part 74. This service is available to licensees of broadcast stations and to broadcast and cable network entities. Broadcast auxiliary microwave stations are used for relaying broadcast television signals from the studio to the transmitter, or between two points such as a main studio and an auxiliary studio. The service also includes mobile television pickups, which relay signals from a remote location back to the studio. 102 13 C.F.R. § 121.201, NAICS code 517210. 103 See Amendment of the Commission’s Rules Regarding the 37.0-38.6 GHz and 38.6-40.0 GHz Bands, ET Docket No. 95-183, Report and Order, 12 FCC Rcd 18600 (1997). 104 Id. 105 See Letter from Aida Alvarez, Administrator, SBA, to Kathleen O’Brien Ham, Chief, Auctions and Industry Analysis Division, WTB, FCC (Feb. 4, 1998); see Letter from Hector Barreto, Administrator, SBA, to Margaret Wiener, Chief, Auctions and Industry Analysis Division, WTB, FCC (Jan. 18, 2002). 106 See Rulemaking to Amend Parts 1, 2, 21, 25, of the Commission’s Rules to Redesignate the 27.5-29.5 GHz Frequency Band, Reallocate the 29.5-30.5 Frequency Band, to Establish Rules and Policies for Local Multipoint Distribution Service and for Fixed Satellite Services, Second Report and Order, Order on Reconsideration, and Fifth Federal Communications Commission FCC 10-58 40 (Continued from previous page) Commission established a small business size standard for LMDS licenses as an entity that has average gross revenues of less than $40 million in the three previous calendar years. 107 An additional small business size standard for “very small business” was added as an entity that, together with its affiliates, has average gross revenues of not more than $15 million for the preceding three calendar years. 108 The SBA has approved these small business size standards in the context of LMDS auctions. 109 There were 93 winning bidders that qualified as small entities in the LMDS auctions. A total of 93 small and very small business bidders won approximately 277 A Block licenses and 387 B Block licenses. In 1999, the Commission re-auctioned 161 licenses; there were 32 small and very small businesses winning that won 119 licenses. 37. Rural Radiotelephone Service. The Commission has not adopted a size standard for small businesses specific to the Rural Radiotelephone Service. 110 A significant subset of the Rural Radiotelephone Service is the Basic Exchange Telephone Radio System (“BETRS”). 111 In the present context, we will use the SBA’s small business size standard applicable to Wireless Telecommunications Carriers (except Satellite), i.e., an entity employing no more than 1,500 persons. 112 There are approximately 1,000 licensees in the Rural Radiotelephone Service, and the Commission estimates that there are 1,000 or fewer small entity licensees in the Rural Radiotelephone Service that may be affected by the rules and policies proposed herein. 38. 1.4 GHz Band Licensees. The Commission conducted an auction of 64 1.4 GHz band licenses 113 in 2007. 114 In that auction, the Commission defined “small business” as an entity that, together with its affiliates and controlling interests, had average gross revenues that exceed $15 million but do not exceed $40 million for the preceding three years, and a “very small business” as an entity that, together with its affiliates and controlling interests, has had average annual gross revenues not exceeding $15 million for the preceding three years. 115 Neither of the two winning bidders sought designated entity status. 116 39. Incumbent 24 GHz Licensees. This analysis may affect incumbent licensees who were relocated to the 24 GHz band from the 18 GHz band, and applicants who wish to provide services in the 24 GHz band. The applicable SBA small business size standard is that of Wireless Telecommunications Carriers (except Satellite). This category provides that such a company is small if it employs no more than 1,500 persons. 117 The broader census data notwithstanding, we believe that there are only two licensees in the 24 GHz band that were relocated from the 18 GHz band, Teligent 118 and TRW, Inc. It is (continued….) Notice of Proposed Rule Making, 12 FCC Rcd 12545, 12689-90, ¶ 348 (1997) (“LMDS Second Report and Order”). 107 See LMDS Second Report and Order, 12 FCC Rcd at 12689-90, ¶ 348. 108 See id. 109 See Alvarez to Phythyon Letter 1998. 110 The service is defined in § 22.99 of the Commission’s Rules, 47 C.F.R. § 22.99. 111 BETRS is defined in §§ 22.757 and 22.759 of the Commission’s Rules, 47 C.F.R. §§ 22.757 and 22.759. 112 13 C.F.R. § 121.201, NAICS code 517210. 113 See “Auction of 1.4 GHz Bands Licenses Scheduled for February 7, 2007,” Public Notice, 21 FCC Rcd 12393 (WTB 2006). 114 See “Auction of 1.4 GHz Band Licenses Closes; Winning Bidders Announced for Auction No. 69,” Public Notice, 22 FCC Rcd 4714 (2007) (“Auction No. 69 Closing PN”). 115 Auction No. 69 Closing PN, Attachment C. 116 See Auction No. 69 Closing PN. 117 13 C.F.R. § 121.201, NAICS code 517210. 118 Teligent acquired the DEMS licenses of FirstMark, the only licensee other than TRW in the 24 GHz band whose Federal Communications Commission FCC 10-58 41 (Continued from previous page) our understanding that Teligent and its related companies have fewer than 1,500 employees, though this may change in the future. TRW is not a small entity. There are approximately 122 licensees in the Rural Radiotelephone Service, and the Commission estimates that there are 122 or fewer small entity licensees in the Rural Radiotelephone Service that may be affected by the rules and policies proposed herein. 40. Future 24 GHz Licensees. With respect to new applicants in the 24 GHz band, we have defined “small business” as an entity that, together with controlling interests and affiliates, has average annual gross revenues for the three preceding years not exceeding $15 million. 119 “Very small business” in the 24 GHz band is defined as an entity that, together with controlling interests and affiliates, has average gross revenues not exceeding $3 million for the preceding three years. 120 The SBA has approved these definitions. 121 The Commission will not know how many licensees will be small or very small businesses until the auction, if required, is held. 41. Broadband Radio Service and Educational Broadband Service. Broadband Radio Service systems, previously referred to as Multipoint Distribution Service (“MDS”) and Multichannel Multipoint Distribution Service (“MMDS”) systems, and “wireless cable,” transmit video programming to subscribers and provide two-way high speed data operations using the microwave frequencies of the Broadband Radio Service (“BRS”) and Educational Broadband Service (“EBS”) (previously referred to as the Instructional Television Fixed Service (“ITFS”)). 122 In connection with the 1996 BRS auction, the Commission established a small business size standard as an entity that had annual average gross revenues of no more than $40 million in the previous three calendar years. 123 The BRS auctions resulted in 67 successful bidders obtaining licensing opportunities for 493 Basic Trading Areas (“BTAs”). Of the 67 auction winners, 61 met the definition of a small business. BRS also includes licensees of stations authorized prior to the auction. At this time, we estimate that of the 61 small business BRS auction winners, 48 remain small business licensees. In addition to the 48 small businesses that hold BTA authorizations, there are approximately 392 incumbent BRS licensees that are considered small entities. 124 After adding the number of small business auction licensees to the number of incumbent licensees not already counted, we find that there are currently approximately 440 BRS licensees that are defined as small businesses under either the SBA or the Commission’s rules. In 2009, the Commission conducted Auction 86, the sale of 78 licenses in the BRS areas. 125 The Commission offered three levels of bidding credits: (i) a bidder with attributed average annual gross revenues that exceed $15 million and license has been modified to require relocation to the 24 GHz band. 119 Amendments to Parts 1, 2, 87 and 101 of the Commission’s Rules To License Fixed Services at 24 GHz, Report and Order, 15 FCC Rcd 16934, 16967, ¶ 77 (2000) (“24 GHz Report and Order”); see also 47 C.F.R. § 101.538(a)(2). 120 24 GHz Report and Order, 15 FCC Rcd at 16967, para. 77; see also 47 C.F.R. § 101.538(a)(1). 121 See Letter from Gary M. Jackson, Assistant Administrator, SBA, to Margaret W. Wiener, Deputy Chief, Auctions and Industry Analysis Division, WTB, FCC (July 28, 2000). 122 Amendment of Parts 21 and 74 of the Commission’s Rules with Regard to Filing Procedures in the Multipoint Distribution Service and in the Instructional Television Fixed Service and Implementation of Section 309(j) of the Communications Act – Competitive Bidding, MM Docket No. 94-131 and PP Docket No. 93-253, Report and Order, 10 FCC Rcd 9589, 9593, ¶ 7 (1995) (“MDS Auction R&O”). 123 47 C.F.R. § 21.961(b)(1). 124 47 U.S.C. § 309(j). Hundreds of stations were licensed to incumbent MDS licensees prior to implementation of Section 309(j) of the Communications Act of 1934, 47 U.S.C. § 309(j). For these pre-auction licenses, the applicable standard is SBA’s small business size standard. 125 Auction of Broadband Radio Service (BRS) Licenses, Scheduled for October 27, 2009, Notice and Filing Requirements, Minimum Opening Bids, Upfront Payments, and Other Procedures for Auction 86, Public Notice, 24 FCC Rcd 8277 (2009). Federal Communications Commission FCC 10-58 42 do not exceed $40 million for the preceding three years (small business) will receive a 15 percent discount on its winning bid; (ii) a bidder with attributed average annual gross revenues that exceed $3 million and do not exceed $15 million for the preceding three years (very small business) will receive a 25 percent discount on its winning bid; and (iii) a bidder with attributed average annual gross revenues that do not exceed $3 million for the preceding three years (entrepreneur) will receive a 35 percent discount on its winning bid. 126 Auction 86 concluded in 2009 with the sale of 61 licenses. 127 Of the ten winning bidders, two bidders that claimed small business status won 4 licenses; one bidder that claimed very small business status won three licenses; and two bidders that claimed entrepreneur status won six licenses. 42. In addition, the SBA’s Cable Television Distribution Services small business size standard is applicable to EBS. There are presently 2,032 EBS licensees. All but 100 of these licenses are held by educational institutions. Educational institutions are included in this analysis as small entities. 128 Thus, we estimate that at least 1,932 licensees are small businesses. Since 2007, Cable Television Distribution Services have been defined within the broad economic census category of Wired Telecommunications Carriers; that category is defined as follows: “This industry comprises establishments primarily engaged in operating and/or providing access to transmission facilities and infrastructure that they own and/or lease for the transmission of voice, data, text, sound, and video using wired telecommunications networks. Transmission facilities may be based on a single technology or a combination of technologies.” 129 The SBA has developed a small business size standard for this category, which is: all such firms having 1,500 or fewer employees. To gauge small business prevalence for these cable services we must, however, use current census data that are based on the previous category of Cable and Other Program Distribution and its associated size standard; that size standard was: all such firms having $13.5 million or less in annual receipts. 130 According to Census Bureau data for 2002, there were a total of 1,191 firms in this previous category that operated for the entire year. 131 Of this total, 1,087 firms had annual receipts of under $10 million, and 43 firms had receipts of $10 million or more but less than $25 million. 132 Thus, the majority of these firms can be considered small. 43. Cable Television Distribution Services. Since 2007, these services have been defined within the broad economic census category of Wired Telecommunications Carriers; that category is defined as follows: “This industry comprises establishments primarily engaged in operating and/or providing access to transmission facilities and infrastructure that they own and/or lease for the transmission of voice, data, text, sound, and video using wired telecommunications networks. 126 Id. at 8296. 127 Auction of Broadband Radio Service Licenses Closes, Winning Bidders Announced for Auction 86, Down Payments Due November 23, 2009, Final Payments Due December 8, 2009, Ten-Day Petition to Deny Period, Public Notice, 24 FCC Rcd 13572 (2009). 128 The term “small entity” within SBREFA applies to small organizations (nonprofits) and to small governmental jurisdictions (cities, counties, towns, townships, villages, school districts, and special districts with populations of less than 50,000). 5 U.S.C. §§ 601(4)-(6). We do not collect annual revenue data on EBS licensees. 129 U.S. Census Bureau, 2007 NAICS Definitions, “517110 Wired Telecommunications Carriers” (partial definition); http://www.census.gov/naics/2007/def/ND517110.HTM#N517110. 130 13 C.F.R. § 121.201, NAICS code 517110. 131 U.S. Census Bureau, 2002 Economic Census, Subject Series: Information, Table 4, Receipts Size of Firms for the United States: 2002, NAICS code 517510 (issued November 2005). 132 Id. An additional 61 firms had annual receipts of $25 million or more. Federal Communications Commission FCC 10-58 43 nual Transmission facilities may be based on a single technology or a combination of technologies.” 133 The SBA has developed a small business size standard for this category, which is: all such firms having 1,500 or fewer employees. To gauge small business prevalence for these cable services we must, however, use current census data that are based on the previous category of Cable and Other Program Distribution and its associated size standard; that size standard was: all such firms having $13.5 million or less in annual receipts. 134 According to Census Bureau data for 2002, there were a total of 1,191 firms in this previous category that operated for the entire year. 135 Of this total, 1,087 firms had an receipts of under $10 million, and 43 firms had receipts of $10 million or more but less than $25 million. 136 Thus, the majority of these firms can be considered small. 44. Cable Companies and Systems. The Commission has also developed its own small business size standards, for the purpose of cable rate regulation. Under the Commission’s rules, a “small cable company” is one serving 400,000 or fewer subscribers, nationwide. 137 Industry data indicate that, of 1,076 cable operators nationwide, all but eleven are small under this size standard. 138 In addition, under the Commission’s rules, a “small system” is a cable system serving 15,000 or fewer subscribers. 139 Industry data indicate that, of 6,635 systems nationwide, 5,802 systems have under 10,000 subscribers, and an additional 302 systems have 10,000-19,999 subscribers. 140 Thus, under this second size standard, most cable systems are small. 45. Cable System Operators. The Communications Act of 1934, as amended, also contains a size standard for small cable system operators, which is “a cable operator that, directly or through an affiliate, serves in the aggregate fewer than 1 percent of all subscribers in the United States and is not affiliated with any entity or entities whose gross annual revenues in the aggregate exceed $250,000,000.” 141 The Commission has determined that an operator serving fewer than 677,000 subscribers shall be deemed a small operator, if its annual revenues, when combined with the total annual revenues of all its affiliates, do not exceed $250 million in the aggregate. 142 Industry data indicate that, of 1,076 cable operators nationwide, all but ten are small under this size standard. 143 We 133 U.S. Census Bureau, 2007 NAICS Definitions, “517110 Wired Telecommunications Carriers” (partial definition); http://www.census.gov/naics/2007/def/ND517110.HTM#N517110. 134 13 C.F.R. § 121.201, NAICS code 517110. 135 U.S. Census Bureau, 2002 Economic Census, Subject Series: Information, Table 4, Receipts Size of Firms for the United States: 2002, NAICS code 517510 (issued November 2005). 136 Id. An additional 61 firms had annual receipts of $25 million or more. 137 47 C.F.R. § 76.901(e). The Commission determined that this size standard equates approximately to a size standard of $100 million or less in annual revenues. Implementation of Sections of the 1992 Cable Act: Rate Regulation, Sixth Report and Order and Eleventh Order on Reconsideration, 10 FCC Rcd 7393, 7408 (1995). 138 These data are derived from: R.R. Bowker, Broadcasting & Cable Yearbook 2006, “Top 25 Cable/Satellite Operators,” pages A-8 & C-2 (data current as of June 30, 2005); Warren Communications News, Television & Cable Factbook 2006, “Ownership of Cable Systems in the United States,” pages D-1805 to D-1857. 139 47 C.F.R. § 76.901(c). 140 Warren Communications News, Television & Cable Factbook 2008, “U.S. Cable Systems by Subscriber Size,” page F-2 (data current as of Oct. 2007). The data do not include 851 systems for which classifying data were not available. 141 47 U.S.C. § 543(m)(2); see 47 C.F.R. § 76.901(f) & nn. 1-3. 142 47 C.F.R. § 76.901(f); see Public Notice, FCC Announces New Subscriber Count for the Definition of Small Cable Operator, DA 01-158 (Cable Services Bureau, Jan. 24, 2001). 143 These data are derived from: R.R. Bowker, Broadcasting & Cable Yearbook 2006, “Top 25 Cable/Satellite Operators,” pages A-8 & C-2 (data current as of June 30, 2005); Warren Communications News, Television & Cable Factbook 2006, “Ownership of Cable Systems in the United States,” pages D-1805 to D-1857. Federal Communications Commission FCC 10-58 44 note that the Commission neither requests nor collects information on whether cable system operators are affiliated with entities whose gross annual revenues exceed $250 million, 144 and therefore we are unable to estimate more accurately the number of cable system operators that would qualify as small under this size standard. 46. Open Video Systems. The open video system (“OVS”) framework was established in 1996, and is one of four statutorily recognized options for the provision of video programming services by local exchange carriers. 145 The OVS framework provides opportunities for the distribution of video programming other than through cable systems. Because OVS operators provide subscription services, 146 OVS falls within the SBA small business size standard covering cable services, which is “Wired Telecommunications Carriers.” 147 The SBA has developed a small business size standard for this category, which is: all such firms having 1,500 or fewer employees. To gauge small business prevalence for such services we must, however, use current census data that are based on the previous category of Cable and Other Program Distribution and its associated size standard; that size standard was: all such firms having $13.5 million or less in annual receipts. 148 According to Census Bureau data for 2002, there were a total of 1,191 firms in this previous category that operated for the entire year. 149 Of this total, 1,087 firms had annual receipts of under $10 million, and 43 firms had receipts of $10 million or more but less than $25 million. 150 Thus, the majority of cable firms can be considered small. In addition, we note that the Commission has certified some OVS operators, with some now providing service. 151 Broadband service providers (“BSPs”) are currently the only significant holders of OVS certifications or local OVS franchises. 152 The Commission does not have financial or employment information regarding the entities authorized to provide OVS, some of which may not yet be operational. Thus, again, at least some of the OVS operators may qualify as small entities. 47. Cable Television Relay Service. This service includes transmitters generally used to relay cable programming within cable television system distribution systems. This cable service is defined within the broad economic census category of Wired Telecommunications Carriers; that category is defined as follows: “This industry comprises establishments primarily engaged in operating and/or providing access to transmission facilities and infrastructure that they own and/or lease for the transmission of voice, data, text, sound, and video using wired telecommunications networks. Transmission facilities may be based on a single technology or a combination of technologies.” 153 The 144 The Commission does receive such information on a case-by-case basis if a cable operator appeals a local franchise authority’s finding that the operator does not qualify as a small cable operator pursuant to § 76.901(f) of the Commission’s rules. See 47 C.F.R. § 76.909(b). 145 47 U.S.C. § 571(a)(3)-(4). See Annual Assessment of the Status of Competition in the Market for the Delivery of Video Programming, Thirteenth Annual Report, 24 FCC Rcd 542, 606 ¶ 135 (2009) (“Thirteenth Annual Cable Competition Report”). 146 See 47 U.S.C. § 573. 147 U.S. Census Bureau, 2007 NAICS Definitions, “517110 Wired Telecommunications Carriers”; http://www.census.gov/naics/2007/def/ND517110.HTM#N517110. 148 13 C.F.R. § 121.201, NAICS code 517110. 149 U.S. Census Bureau, 2002 Economic Census, Subject Series: Information, Table 4, Receipts Size of Firms for the United States: 2002, NAICS code 517510 (issued November 2005). 150 Id. An additional 61 firms had annual receipts of $25 million or more. 151 A list of OVS certifications may be found at http://www.fcc.gov/mb/ovs/csovscer.html. 152 See Thirteenth Annual Cable Competition Report, 24 FCC Rcd at 606-07 ¶ 135. BSPs are newer firms that are building state-of-the-art, facilities-based networks to provide video, voice, and data services over a single network. 153 U.S. Census Bureau, 2007 NAICS Definitions, “517110 Wired Telecommunications Carriers” (partial definition); http://www.census.gov/naics/2007/def/ND517110.HTM#N517110. Federal Communications Commission FCC 10-58 45 SBA has developed a small business size standard for this category, which is: all such firms having 1,500 or fewer employees. To gauge small business prevalence for cable services we must, however, use current census data that are based on the previous category of Cable and Other Program Distribution and its associated size standard; that size standard was: all such firms having $13.5 million or less in annual receipts. 154 According to Census Bureau data for 2002, there were a total of 1,191 firms in this previous category that operated for the entire year. 155 Of this total, 1,087 firms had annual receipts of under $10 million, and 43 firms had receipts of $10 million or more but less than $25 million. 156 Thus, the majority of these firms can be considered small. 48. Multichannel Video Distribution and Data Service. MVDDS is a terrestrial fixed microwave service operating in the 12.2-12.7 GHz band. The Commission adopted criteria for defining three groups of small businesses for purposes of determining their eligibility for special provisions such as bidding credits. It defined a very small business as an entity with average annual gross revenues not exceeding $3 million for the preceding three years; a small business as an entity with average annual gross revenues not exceeding $15 million for the preceding three years; and an entrepreneur as an entity with average annual gross revenues not exceeding $40 million for the preceding three years. 157 These definitions were approved by the SBA. 158 On January 27, 2004, the Commission completed an auction of 214 MVDDS licenses (Auction No. 53). In this auction, ten winning bidders won a total of 192 MVDDS licenses. 159 Eight of the ten winning bidders claimed small business status and won 144 of the licenses. The Commission also held an auction of MVDDS licenses on December 7, 2005 (Auction 63). Of the three winning bidders who won 22 licenses, two winning bidders, winning 21 of the licenses, claimed small business status. 160 49. Internet Service Providers. The 2007 Economic Census places these firms, whose services might include voice over Internet protocol (VoIP), in either of two categories, depending on whether the service is provided over the provider’s own telecommunications connections (e.g. cable and DSL, ISPs), or over client-supplied telecommunications connections (e.g. dial-up ISPs). The former are within the category of Wired Telecommunications Carriers, 161 which has an SBA small business size standard of 1,500 or fewer employees. 162 The latter are within the category of All Other 154 13 C.F.R. § 121.201, NAICS code 517110. 155 U.S. Census Bureau, 2002 Economic Census, Subject Series: Information, Table 4, Receipts Size of Firms for the United States: 2002, NAICS code 517510 (issued November 2005). 156 Id. An additional 61 firms had annual receipts of $25 million or more. 157 Amendment of Parts 2 and 25 of the Commission’s Rules to Permit Operation of NGSO FSS Systems Co- Frequency with GSO and Terrestrial Systems in the Ku-Band Frequency Range; Amendment of the Commission’s Rules to Authorize Subsidiary Terrestrial Use of the 12.2-12.7 GHz Band by Direct Broadcast Satellite Licenses and their Affiliates; and Applications of Broadwave USA, PDC Broadband Corporation, and Satellite Receivers, Ltd. to provide A Fixed Service in the 12.2-12.7 GHz Band, ET Docket No. 98-206, Memorandum Opinion and Order and Second Report and Order, 17 FCC Rcd 9614, 9711, ¶ 252 (2002). 158 See Letter from Hector V. Barreto, Administrator, U.S. Small Business Administration, to Margaret W. Wiener, Chief, Auctions and Industry Analysis Division, WTB, FCC (Feb.13, 2002). 159 See “Multichannel Video Distribution and Data Service Auction Closes,” Public Notice, 19 FCC Rcd 1834 (2004). 160 See “Auction of Multichannel Video Distribution and Data Service Licenses Closes; Winning Bidders Announced for Auction No. 63,” Public Notice, 20 FCC Rcd 19807 (2005). 161 U.S. Census Bureau, 2007 NAICS Definitions, “517110 Wired Telecommunications Carriers”, http://www.census.gov/naics/2007/def/ND517110.HTM#N517110. 162 13 C.F.R. § 121.201, NAICS code 517110 (updated for inflation in 2008). Federal Communications Commission FCC 10-58 46 Telecommunications, 163 which has a size standard of annual receipts of $25 million or less. 164 The most current Census Bureau data for all such firms, however, are the 2002 data for the previous census category called Internet Service Providers. 165 That category had a small business size standard of $21 million or less in annual receipts, which was revised in late 2005 to $23 million. The 2002 data show that there were 2,529 such firms that operated for the entire year. 166 Of those, 2,437 firms had annual receipts of under $10 million, and an additional 47 firms had receipts of between $10 million and $24,999,999. 167 Consequently, we estimate that the majority of ISP firms are small entities. 50. The ISP industry has changed dramatically since 2002. The 2002 data cited above may therefore include entities that no longer provide Internet access service and may exclude entities that now provide such service. To ensure that this IRFA describes the universe of small entities that our action might affect, we discuss in turn several different types of entities that might be providing Internet access service. 51. We note that, although we have no specific information on the number of small entities that provide Internet access service over unlicensed spectrum, we include these entities in our IRFA. IV. Description of Projected Reporting, Recordkeeping and Other Compliance Requirements: 52. As discussed above, the NPRM seeks comment on a number of specific reforms to contain the growth in the legacy high-cost support mechanisms and identify savings that can be shifted toward broadband. 168 Under the Commission’s current rules, eligible telecommunications carriers (ETCs) file certain information with the Commission, the Universal Service Administrative Company (USAC), and/or the National Carrier Exchange Association (NECA) that is used to determine the amount of high-cost support each ETC receives. The proposals in the NPRM to cap or eliminate support, if eventually adopted, are not likely to substantially change the current reporting, recordkeeping, and compliance requirements, and would, in some cases, reduce such burdens. The proposal to shift rate-of-return carriers to incentive regulation likely would result in certain one-time reporting requirements related to the conversion, such as establishing initial price cap indexes for price cap baskets. 169 In addition, some ongoing reporting, recordkeeping and other compliance requirements may change after the conversion from rate-of-return regulation, but may result in less burdensome requirements, in some cases. We do not have an estimate of potential reporting, recordkeeping, and compliance burdens, because it is too speculative at this time to anticipate the number of carriers that would be required to convert to incentive regulation, or what type of incentive regulation would be required. We anticipate that commenters will provide the Commission with reliable information on any costs and burdens on small entities. V. Steps Taken to Minimize Significant Economic Impact on Small Entities, and Significant Alternatives Considered: 163 U.S. Census Bureau, 2007 NAICS Definitions, “517919 All Other Telecommunications”; http://www.census.gov/naics/2007/def/ND517919.HTM#N517919. 164 13 C.F.R. § 121.201, NAICS code 517919 (updated for inflation in 2008). 165 U.S. Census Bureau, “2002 NAICS Definitions, “518111 Internet Service Providers”; http://www.census.gov/eped/naics02/def/NDEF518.HTM. 166 U.S. Census Bureau, 2002 Economic Census, Subject Series: Information, “Establishment and Firm Size (Including Legal Form of Organization),” Table 4, NAICS code 518111 (issued Nov. 2005). 167 An additional 45 firms had receipts of $25 million or more. 168 See supra para. 3. 169 See NPRM, para. 55 note 122. Federal Communications Commission FCC 10-58 47 53. The RFA requires an agency to describe any significant alternatives that it has considered in reaching its approach, which may include the following four alternatives, among others: (1) the establishment of differing compliance or reporting requirements or timetables that take into account the resources available to small entities; (2) the clarification, consolidation, or simplification of compliance or reporting requirements under the rule for small entities; (3) the use of performance, rather than design, standards; and (4) an exemption from coverage of the rule, or any part thereof, for small entities. 170 54. As discussed above, the NPRM seeks comment the NPRM seeks comment on capping legacy high-cost support provided to incumbent telephone companies; shifting rate-of-return carriers to incentive regulation and converting interstate common line support to a frozen amount per line; eliminating interstate access support; and eliminating high-cost support for competitive eligible telecommunications carriers. 171 The NPRM seeks comment generally on the proposed universal service reforms and carriers’ rates under the Commission’s current pricing rules, and specifically seeks comment on whether there are special considerations resulting from the operation of the NECA pool that would unfairly advantage or disadvantage certain carriers. 172 The NPRM also seeks comment on the cost s and benefits that would be realized by converting all rate-of-return carriers to price cap or other incentive regulation. 173 We anticipate that the record will reflect whether the overall benefits of such a requirement would outweigh the burdens on small entities, and if so, suggest alternative ways in which the Commission could lessen the overall burdens on small entities. We encourage small entity comment. VI. Federal Rules that May Duplicate, Overlap, or Conflict with the Proposed Rules: 55. None. 170 5 U.S.C. § 603. 171 See supra, para. 3. 172 See NPRM, para. 54. The NECA pool is composed of rate-of-return carriers that generally are much smaller than the price cap carriers. 173 See NPRM, para. 55. Federal Communications Commission FCC 10-58 48 APPENDIX B Comments of 61 Economists     Comments of 61 Concerned Economists    Using Procurement Auctions to Allocate Broadband Stimulus Grants    Submitted to the Nati ation Agency (NTIA)  onal Telecommunications Inform and Rura e (RUS) l Utilities Servic April 13, 2009    Contacts:  Paul Milgrom  Economics Department    Stanford University  579 Serra Mall at Galvez tanford, CA 94305  ilgrom@stanford.edu  S m   nomic Policy Research  Gregory Rosston  Stanford Institute for Eco   Stanford University  579 Serra Mall at Galvez Stanford, CA 94305  grosston@stanford.edu  Andrzej Skrzypacz  usiness Graduate School of B Stanford University  350 Memorial Way  tanford, CA  94305  ndy@gsb.stanford.edu  S a   ute  Scott Wallsten  Technology Policy Instit 05  1401 Eye St., NW  Washington, DC 200 scott@wallsten.net      Executive Summary  The signatories to this document are economists who have studied telecommunications,  auctions, and competition policy. 1  While we may disagree about the stimulus package, we  believe that it is important to implement mechanisms that make stimulus spending as  efficient as possible.  To that end, we have come together to encourage the National  elecommunications Information Agency (NTIA) and Rural Utilities Service (RUS) to adopt T auction mechanisms to allocate broadband stimulus grants.    The broadband stimulus NOI asks which mechanisms NTIA and RUS should use to  distribute grants and how those mechanisms address shortcomings in traditional grant and  loan programs. In this note we explain why procurement auctions are more efficient and  more consistent with the stimulus goals of allocating funds quickly than a traditional grant  review process.  We recommend that NTIA/RUS use procurement auctions to distribute at  least part of the stimulus funds.  The American Recovery and Reinvestment Act (ARRA) requires NTIA/RUS to distribute  $7.2 billion in broadband subsidies.  The broadband component of the Act has dual, and not  entirely consistent, objectives of providing immediate economic stimulus and improving  broadband service.  NTIA/RUS faces a formidable challenge in determining how to spend  the money quickly and efficiently in ways that meet these goals.  The traditional grant  application process is long, complicated, and involves subjective and arbitrary decisions  egarding which projects to fund.  In other words, requesting and reviewing grant r applications is not an effective way to implement the plan.    Procurement auctions, in contrast, provide a mechanism that can allocate grant money  quickly, efficiently, and according to well?defined rules.  As a result, procurement auctions  offer NTIA/RUS the most promising method of maximizing broadband improvement while  also creating some level of “temporary, timely, and targeted” stimulus.  We therefore  trongly recommend that NTIA/RUS adopt procurement auctions as its preferred method s of distributing grants.    This memo has three parts.  First, it explains why the traditional grant application process  is unsuitable for this task and why procurement auctions are better suited.  Second, it  sketches out a procurement auction plan.  This plan is intended to be a starting point from  which auction design experts would proceed to build and implement a fully functional  auction. Finally, we explain that even if policymakers are skeptical of procurement  auctions, one could be implemented quickly as part of an initial tranche of stimulus funding  in order to test its efficacy relative to traditional approaches. This approach would allow  TIA/RUS to quickly expand upon or modify the procurement auction program in  ubsequent funding rounds.   N s                                                            1  The analysis and opinions here in are the sole responsibility of the signatories to these comments.  The  signatories are not appearing on behalf of any other person or entity and have received no compensation for  the production of these comments.          Table of Contents  I. Introduction ...................................................................................................................................................... 1 II. Pr ocurement Auctions are more Efficient than Traditional Grantmaking Approaches .. 2 A. Traditional Approaches for Distributing Grants are Cumbersome and Slow ................. 2 B. Procurement Auctions Can Allocate Funds Flexibly, Efficiently and Fairly ..................... 3 . ........... 4 C Clear Selection Criteria are Critical for any Selection Program .................................. III. A Straw?Man Procurement Auction Plan for Allocating NTIA/RUS Broadband  Su id bs ies ...................................................................................................................................................................... 5 A. Auction Design ............................................................................................................................................ 5 B. Process Considerations ........................................................................................................................... 6 C. Compliance and Accountability ........................................................................................................... 8 IV. NTIA/RUS Should Use Procurement Auctions to Allocate a At Least A Portion of the  First Wave of Broadband Stimulus Funding and Expand the Program if Successful ................. 9 . Conclusion....................................................................................................................................................... 10 V   1    which auction design expert I. Introduction  The signatories to this document are economists who have studied telecommunications,  auctions, and competition policy. 2  While we may disagree about the stimulus package, we  believe that it is important to implement mechanisms that make stimulus spending as  efficient as possible.  To that end, we have come together to encourage the National  elecommunications Information Agency (NTIA) and Rural Utilities Service (RUS) to adopt T auction mechanisms to allocate broadband stimulus grants.    The broadband stimulus NOI asks which mechanisms NTIA and RUS should use to  distribute grants and how those mechanisms address shortcomings in traditional grant and  loan programs. 3  In this note we explain why procurement auctions are more efficient and  more consistent with the stimulus goals of allocating funds quickly than a traditional grant  review process.  We recommend that NTIA/RUS use procurement auctions to distribute at  least part of the stimulus funds. 4   The American Recovery and Reinvestment Act (ARRA) requires NTIA/RUS to distribute  $7.2 billion in broadband subsidies.  The broadband component of the Act has dual, and not  entirely consistent, objectives of providing immediate economic stimulus and improving  broadband service.  NTIA/RUS faces a formidable challenge in determining how to spend  the money quickly and efficiently in ways that meet these goals.  The traditional grant  application process is long, complicated, and involves subjective and arbitrary decisions  egarding which projects to fund.  In other words, requesting and reviewing grant r applications is not an effective way to implement the plan.    Procurement auctions, in contrast, provide a mechanism that can allocate grant money  quickly, efficiently, and according to well?defined rules.  As a result, procurement auctions  offer NTIA/RUS the most promising method of maximizing broadband improvement while  also creating some level of “temporary, timely, and targeted” stimulus.  We therefore  trongly recommend that NTIA/RUS adopt procurement auctions as its preferred method s of distributing grants.    This memo has three parts.  First, it explains why the traditional grant application process  is unsuitable for this task and why procurement auctions are better suited.  Second, it  sketches out a procurement auction plan.  This plan is intended to be a starting point from  s would proceed to build and implement a fully functional                                                           2  The analysis and opinions here in are the sole responsibility of the signatories to these comments.  The  s or ignatories are not appearing on behalf of any other person or entity and have received no compensation f the production of these comments.  3  Section 5a asks: “What mechanisms for distributing stimulus funds should be used by NTIA and USDA in  addition to traditional grant and loan programs?” Section 5b asks: “How would these mechanisms address  shortcomings, if any, in traditional grant or loan mechanisms in the context of the Recovery Act?”  Because the  l  egislation appears to forbid the of use demand?side vouchers for the vast majority of the stimulus money, we have focussed on supply?side mechanisms.  4  The term “reverse auction” has been used in the context of universal service as a synonym for procurement  auction.  2    dollars.  auction. Finally, we explain that even if policymakers are skeptical of procurement  auctions, one could be implemented quickly as part of an initial tranche of stimulus funding  in order to test its efficacy relative to traditional approaches. This approach would allow  TIA/RUS to quickly expand upon or modify the procurement auction program in  ubsequent funding rounds.   N s   II. Procurement Auctions are more Efficient than Traditional  Grantmaking Approaches  A. Traditional Approaches for Distributing Grants are Cumbersome and Sl Traditionally, subsidy programs require firms to submit lengthy applications and the  government to pick the “best ones” after reviewing all the competing applications.  This  pproach has at least three problems for the purpose of distributing the funds from the  ow  a stimulus bill.    First, the traditional approach is inherently time?consuming.  Firms must complete  complex proposals that government officials must subsequently spend time reviewing.   USDA’s Rural Utility Service (RUS), whose awards include broadband support, noted in its  2007 Annual Report that in 2006 the average application took six months to process (and  this was an improvement from previous years when the average processing time was  nearly a year). 5   That estimate does not include time firms spent preparing those  pplications.  Complex broadband grants have taken far longer—s everal years in some a instances. 6   Such delays are inconsistent with the goals of speedy stimulus grants.    Second, the qualitative nature of the applications makes it difficult to compare one project  to another.  For example, it will be difficult to choose between, say, a fiber project in Texas  and a wireless project in North Dakota.  Reviewing and deciding between large numbers of  grant applications will inevitably lead to inconsistent and seemingly arbitrary decisions.  nd, the unpredictability of decisions will make it harder for companies to determine and A propose the most appropriate projects.     Third, it is difficult to design a grant application system to ensure that firms receive only  the minimum subsidy necessary to achieve a goal.  To determine the “correct” subsidy level  the government could attempt to calculate the necessary subsidy using available  information, but this effort would be time?intensive, costly, and inaccurate.  Alternatively, it  could rely on the applicant’s own estimate, but applicants have little incentive to ask for the  bare minimum required.  Either approach will result in a suboptimal allocation of subsidy                                                           5  USDA Rural Utility Service. 2007. USDA Rural Development: Bringing Broadband to Rural America. http://www.rurdev.usda.gov/rd/pubs/RDBroadbandRpt.pdf  6  Open Range Communications disclosed that it had spent over three years and submitted over 30,000 pages  of application materials before its RDUP loan was granted. See  http://www.businesswire.com/news/google/20071022006575/en  3    Procurement auctions have s g   Reviewing grant applications is not an appropriate way to distribute broadband stimulus  grants.  NTIA/RUS requires a more objective and efficient methodology.  Competitive  bidding by procurement auction is the best approach.  B. Procurement Auctions Can Allocate Funds Flexibly, Efficiently and Fairly  An objective, ”mechanistic” approach that applies specific, quantitative criteria can be both  easier to implement and lead to more efficient outcomes than traditional grant application  eview. Procurement auctions, in particular, can lead to more efficient grant disbursal than r traditional qualitative approaches. 7     An auction is a mechanism for making smart allocation choices when confronted with  overwhelming amounts of information and no relevant market exists.  In a typical auction  for a good, bids increase until the auction identifies the entity willing to pay the most for  the good being auctioned.  In the simplest procurement or “reverse” auction, bids consist of  how much an entity must be paid to provide a good or service.  The procurement auction  hus identifies the entity willing to provide the good or service for the smallest amount of t money.    Though it may sound exotic, a procurement auction is just a competitive bidding process  and analogous to any government procurement.  When the government needs to purchase  something, it describes specifically what it wants, firms submit bids to provide the service,  and the government picks the firm that submits the best bid. 8   The best bid may be the  lowest, but the government may also take other factors into account when making the  decision, especially in the case of complex projects. 9    In procurement auctions for broadband, the government would specify its objective and  ask firms to bid for the right to meet that objective.  Consider, for example, a rural area with  no broadband service.  The government can ask firms to bid for a subsidy that would make  it profitable for the firm to provide service.  Firms and other organizations would compete  against each other by bidding down the subsidy they need to offer service.  The firm that  . commits to provide broadband in that area for the smallest subsidy would win the grant everal advantages over traditional methods of distributing  n rules are in place they relieve the government of the task of rants.  First, once the auctio                                                          7  The Federal Communications Commission (FCC) and Congress realized more than a decade ago that the  traditional proposal?review approach was inefficient.  Historically the FCC had granted spectrum licenses  based on comparative hearings.  These hearings could not be done quickly and put the FCC in the impossible  position of processing tractor trailer?loads of paperwork to decide which companies were best suited to  providing services in a given spectrum band.  In 1994, the FCC began to allocate spectrum via auctions, which  could occur quickly and allocate spectrum far more efficiently than could any administrative comparative  p   rocess.  This model has been used successfully in the U.S. and around the world ever since.  8 See some federal procurement guidelines here: http://www.whitehouse.gov/omb/procurement/index_guides.html 9 While it is easier to conduct this process for simple products, the government also uses it to supply highly  complex goods like weapons systems See, for example, http://www.nytimes.com/2008/03/10/business/worldbusiness/10tanker.html?fta=y and www.gao.gov/cgi- bin/getrpt?GAO-06-364.   4      identifying the “best” projects – the government sets forth its objectives in advance of the  auction.  This also enables and encourages bidders to tailor their projects to the  government’s actual criteria. Second, because auctions use competition among providers to  determine the subsidy required to achieve any particular goal, the government does not  have to estimate the subsidy actually required for any given project. Reducing the subsidy  for any given project frees up money that can be used for additional projects.  Finally, they  inherently induce firms to contribute their own investment to increase the chance that  their bid is accepted. 10    C. Clear Selection Criteria are Critical for any Selection Program    Crucial to the success of any plan, not just procurement auctions, is having clear objectives.   In the case of the broadband stimulus the objectives include creating new jobs and  improving broadband.  It is not possible to maximize both objectives simultaneously.  From  the language of the Act and public discussions about it thus far we can assume that the  ost important objective is to maximize new broadband availability subject to creating m some minimum level of new economic activity.    In general, stimulus funds would be awarded to those bidders that maximize broadband  expansion with the lowest subsidy amount. Through the auction process bidders would be  ble to “bid down” the subsidy as they compete with other bidders seeking the same a stimulus dollars.    Careful auction design is crucial to ensuring an efficient outcome.  It is important to keep in  mind two general points.  First, the criteria on which the bids will be scored or ranked must  be clear.  As a simple example, bids could consist of subsidy requested per household  connected or per household to which broadband service is newly available. 11   Then bids  ould be ranked from smallest subsidy requested to the largest, and funds distributed c according to that ranking.    Second, the ability to “game” the procurement process increases with the ambiguity of the  rules and the number of criteria included in a bid.  For example, an auction in which firms  had to demonstrate that their bid was in the “public interest” and specify a subsidy per  household, the number of new households served, the service speeds, reliability, latency,  obility, and price would probably not work well due to the ambiguity of what, exactly,  public interest” means and the large number of criteria on which firms bid.  m “                                                          10  Procurement auctions are sound and have been used successfully around the world to bring  telecommunications services to areas that previously had none.  Experiences in other countries, including  Australia, India, Chile, Peru, and others demonstrate that procurement auctions can substantially bring down  th the e subsidies required to induce buildout.  Their experiences also teach us that it will be important to get  details right.  11  It will be important not to confuse supply and demand for broadband.  About half of all people without  broadband say that they are not interested in it.  Because the stimulus focuses primarily on supply, we may  want to focus on newly available broadband as opposed to newly adopted.  5    more involved measure such Note that the need to identify unambiguous, simple criteria on which to judge bids in  advance of the auction is actually an advantage, not a disadvantage, of procurement  auctions.  It may appear at first blush that traditional grant reviews do not face similar  roblems, but that is incorrect.  If a grant review process does not undergo the same p identification task then it will likely lead to arbitrary and inconsistent decisions.    In addition to those very general points, this auction must be designed in a way that does  not arbitrarily benefit one technology over another.  Organizations could, therefore, bid to  upgrade copper services in order to make DSL feasible, upgrade or install coaxial cable to  facilitate cable broadband, or upgrade or install wireless and satellite broadband  quipment.   With scoring rules set out in advance bidders could know how they would  ave to bid and consider competing technologies or providers in other geographic areas.  e h   III. A Straw?Man Procurement Auction Plan for Allocating NTIA/RUS  Broadband Subsidies  A. Auction Design  This section describes economic methodology and other considerations for devising an  effective procurement auction program.  The detailed rules of the auction will be crucial, as  hey will affect the outcome.t 12   NTIA/RUS will have to make several decisions as it creates  these rules.  We list some of the issues below.    The first step is the same for both a procurement auction and a traditional grant review  process: NTIA/RUS must identify and define unserved and underserved regions.  Ideally,  most of these regions would be specified to have similar numbers of  unserved/underserved households, so that the service costs across regions can be easily  compared, and to be just large enough that projects of that scale are meaningful to the  bidders. NTIA/RUS could identify these areas using existing data or bidders could propose  nd certify unserved areas.  Each eligible project would need to offer qualifying service to a at least 95% of the unserved households in the region. 13      Having defined either the regions or the mechanism for defining the regions, the rules for  the procurement auction begin to diverge from the traditional grant review process.   NTIA/RUS should set out a framework for scoring projects in terms of a standard unit of  supply. This could be a simple metric, such as “newly served population” (defined as the  population to which service above a minimum bandwidth threshold is newly available) or a   as “effective bandwidth supplied” (defined as the population                                                           12  If there is enough time, it would be useful to design experiments to test auction rules.  In section III, we  suggest allocating the money in tranches to learn about the process and make changes based on those  outcomes.      13  The required percentage of homes in the area could be set at a different level, or it could be set by the  bidders and scored as part of the auction evaluation.  6    Technology Opportunities Pr While ARRA does not  to which service is newly available adjusted for the speed of service. 14 )   Each bid would be  characterized in terms of effective supply and cost.  We advise against introducing  additional dimensions to the evaluation. It is particularly problematic to introduce  ubjective criteria, which undermine the quick and objective comparisons required by an s effective auction.     n a sealed?bid auction, the winning bids maximize the total effective supply, subject to the I government’s spending and other constraints.     Ideally, the government would include multiple regions with a limited budget in a single  auction, in order to encourage competition among bidders offering diverse services in  different areas. Particularly in large auctions, the government should allow bidders to  specify a maximum number of projects that they might win from any non?overlapping sets  of projects and a further maximum for collections of such sets of projects. By protecting  idders from the risk of winning too many projects in any set and overall, this feature b encourages firms to submit additional proposals, increasing the level of competition.     Auctions are adaptable to respect a wide range of policy concerns. The government could  use instruments similar to ones that have been employed in FCC auctions, such as limiting  the number of projects won by any single bidder or offering bidding credits to small  businesses. And, to spread the effects of the subsidy geographically, the government could  ive greater weight to the first households served in a state or region than to additional g households.     We recommend that pay?as?bid pricing applies: winning bidders should provide the project  nd receive the subsidy described in their bids.  This system is simple and pay?as?bid a pricing is common in procurement auctions.     The variations we have described relate to characteristics of the bidder or the region being  served. It is easy in principle to add other sorts of factors to the bidding menu. However,  the more dimensions on which firms bid, the more likely it becomes that there are easy  ways for firms to game the system.  We recommend limiting the factors to price and  effective supply, especially in the first implementation to test the auction system. With a  traightforward first step, auctions can be implemented rapidly and realize most of the  ompetitive benefits from moving to this type of system.  s c   B. Process Considerations  As a threshold matter, procurement auctions are allowed under ARRA.  The Broadband  ogram was established to provide “competitive grants.” 15    tely define the term “competitive grant,” procurement auctions separa                                                          14  An adjustment factor would reward bidders for providing higher speed service to unserved population. For  ex e could have a factor of 1, 10 mbps a factor of 1.5, 50 mbps, a factor of 2 and 100 mbps, ample, 1 mbps servic a factor of 3.  15  ARRA, Sec. 6001(g).  7    qualified to bid in the origina ho are simply a methodology for implementing a competitive grant program, and in this  respect should be seen as the fairest and most transparent way of doing so. 16   The framework around which an effective procurement auction can be built is simple, and  immediately suggests where substantial improvements over traditional grant review or  other types of procurement auction can be made.    Indication of Intent and Prescreening.  In order to avoid an extended post? bidding process of weeding out and correcting frivolous bidding and overbidding, a  procurement auction process must include a pre?bid indication of intent from prospective  bidders and a simple prescreening process.  Prescreening could be as simple as a statement  committing to meet all requirements of ARRA and the procurement auction rules, coupled  with a showing that the bidder can (1) meet ARRA’s 20% contribution requirement and (2)  pay debts up to the subsidies it receive. 17     Substantive Preconditions.  In order to limit the considerations for award as much  as possible, everything extraneous to price should be made a precondition to bid – that is,  any bid will assume the preconditions and any cost of compliance to be included in the bid.   Doing so will increase transparency and limit the subjectivity of the final decision?making  process.  For example, in implementing the open access requirement, NTIA should set its  rule and require bidders to meet it – bids that do not comply with the rule will be rejected.   Allowing bidders to opt out of specific substantive requirements would invite gaming and  undermine the objectivity of the procurement auction, removing the rationale for using an  auction in the first place.  Thus, NTIA should establish specific requirements for how it  wants bidders to meet the substantive requirements set forth in Section 6001(e) through  (h) of ARRA.  Moreover, bids that fail to include clear metrics and reporting intervals  consistent with these requirements should be rejected.  Combinatorial Bids and Trading.  Just as ARRA requires that competitive grants  be technologically neutral, the size and scope of bidders has also been left open.  Indeed,  ARRA appears to encourage a broad range of types and sizes of bidders.  This range reflects  an underlying emphasis in ARRA’s broadband sections on flexibility and creativity – letting  the market figure out the best way of allocating funds and expanding broadband.  Rules for  procurement auctions should further the goal of flexibility by making clear that bidders  may combine to serve specific areas, or combine areas, as their bids may specify.   Furthermore, subject to full compliance with implementing rules, NTIA should allow rights  to receive the subsidy, once won, to be freely traded.  Winners should be allowed to  subcontract or transfer their obligation to another entity that would have otherwise been  l auction.  A precondition for a workable trading system,  ar and enforced benchmarks and buildout expectations.  wever, is that there are cle                                                          16  For a regulation to survive a challenge under the Administrative Procedure Act, a court must conclude that  the regulation was not “arbitrary and capricious” or an “abuse of discretion.”  Given the benefits of using  procurement auctions to distribute competitive grants, and ARRA’s clear emphasis on speedy distribution of  gr  ants, an agency deciding to distribute funds under ARRA that opted for a less efficient and less transparent method would likely be required to explain what other factors made its decision reasonable.  17  In order to avoid tipping their hands too early, a series of ranges of subsidies can be established, with the  rules specifying that combined bids would be assumed to be able to meet the total of the combined ranges.  8    outcome may make it possib                                          Provided that the underlying build out and other performance requirements are met,  creating a trading system will allow winners to consolidate or diversify their obligations in  a rational and efficient manner.  Transparency of Information.  To the maximum extent possible, and consistent  with how other auctions such as spectrum auctions have been conducted, information  about the winning bidder or bidders, the amounts bid, and performance assurances must  be made public and easily accessible online.  It has already been established that  transparency of information in a procurement auction does not violate any confidentiality  of bidders that might otherwise be protected under the Federal Procurement Regulations.   18   Accordingly, NTIA should make this explicit in its implementing regulations, and explain  that transparency of the process is essential not only to ensure fairness of the auction itself  but also to aid in compliance.  C. Compliance and Accountability  Any subsidy or procurement plan—auction or otherwise—must include a strong  mechanism for determining that firms fulfill their obligations. Performance and related  assurances, such as performance bonds and other mechanisms apply to any grant program  and are not unique to procurement auctions.  No matter what mechanism NTIA might  choose to allocate competitive grants, it will still have to address compliance and auditing.   To some extent, simple prescreening of bidders will address compliance issues by ensuring  that only serious bidders are engaging in the process.  However, NTIA must also apply  traditional performance assurance mechanisms, which are briefly discussed here.   It may be possible to require winning firms to put money in escrow that will be returned to  them once they can certify that they have met their obligations (or returned in tranches as  they show progress towards the goal). Forfeiture bonds are another approach. The auction  design itself may be an important factor in determining whether post?auction obligations  are met.   Winning bidders must make good on their bids.  Holding them accountable and making  ure that the subsidy actually created new economic activity requires two conditions to be s true.    First, the firm must undertake the promised investment within a specified period of time.   The firm should be given part of the subsidy immediately so that it can begin construction  and receive the remainder in increments related to the number of households to which it  as provided access.  Firms that do not meet the promises made in their bids should be h penalized to ensure that they have sufficient incentive to meet their obligations.      Second, the investment must not have occurred without the subsidy.  Whether the  investment is inframarginal is very difficult to know and it may not be possible to  determine the answer conclusively for any given firm.  Nevertheless, evaluating the  le to discern the amount of new investment created.                      18  Matter of: MTB Group, Inc., 2005 WL 433615, 2005 U.S. Comp. Gen. LEXIS 34 (2006)  9    IV. NTIA/RUS Should Use Procurement Auctions to Allocate a At Least  A Portion of the First Wave of Broadband Stimulus Funding and  Expand the Program if Successful  We realize that using competitive auctions for disbursing subsidy grants may be viewed as  a change in process and that there may be some risk.  As such, if auctions are not used for  the entire subsidy process, we think that at least some real world analysis should take  place to see how auctions perform compared to the traditional process rather than  rejecting auctions completely. This section describes how such an incremental approach to  using auctions could be implemented in the grant system.  As NTIA/RUS have indicated, the stimulus awards are likely to be awarded over time.  We  believe that that NTIA/RUS would be wise to disburse broadband grants in successive  waves or rounds, so that it can improve its disbursal mechanisms iteratively throughout  the lifecycle of the program. Within this context, we recommend that NTIA/RUS designate  one or more geographical regions in which the first wave of funds is distributed exclusively  through a procurement auction process.   This approach sets up a natural experiment allowing comparison of procurement auctions  to the traditional approach. If the experiment is successful, the procurement auction  mechanism can be expanded in scope to encompass other regions and stimulus dollars  (potentially all remaining stimulus funds). Regardless of what mechanism is ultimately  used, the lessons from the procurement auction pilot will help NTIA/RUS to learn and  adapt its award mechanisms.    A procurement auction can be implemented quickly. While there are many options for  designing the auction system, that fact should not serve as an argument against auctions:   auctions can be implemented rapidly.  In fact, auctions may take a little more time to design  upfront than a generic submission system, but the investment upfront is likely to speed the  overall process because it will make selection much more rapid and less arbitrary (and  hence less subject to ex post litigation).  Other countries have proposed and implemented  procurement auctions for universal service rapidly and successfully. 19     One way to use auctions for a portion of the first wave of stimulus grants would be to  divide the  country into large geographical regions. The “Regional Economic Area  Grouping” (REAG) used by the FCC in spectrum auctions is one possible scheme to  consider. In this scheme, the continental United States is divided into six regions, each  containing roughly 50 million citizens and encompassing both rural and urban areas. An  alternative would be to designate similarly?sized regions as aggregations of states.  Whatever scheme is used, it is important that the regions are roughly similar in terms of  population size and urban/rural mix.                                                           19  See Wallsten, Scott,  “Reverse Auctions and Universal Telecommunications Service: Lessons from Global  Experience” Federal Communications Law Journal.  http://www.law.indiana.edu/fclj/pubs/v61/no2/9? WALLSTENFINAL.pdf  10    Then, in the first wave of stimulus disbursal, regions consisting of one?third of the U.S.  population (roughly 100 million citizens) would be served through procurement auction of  stimulus funds. The remaining two?thirds would be served by a conventional grant review  process. A timeline would be established requiring that the first wave of funds—whether  by procurement auction or by traditional grant review—shall be completed within six  months. The amount of funding allocated to the first wave should reflect a practical  assessment of what is feasible to disburse using the traditional process in a six?month  timeframe. At the end of the period, the NTIA/RUS should take one month to compare  results of the two programs and to assess the results, before making a determination  whether to use procurement auctions in subsequent rounds.   Should NTIA/RUS decide to continue or expand the use of procurement auctions, the  mechanism can be tweaked to incorporate lessons from the first wave. However, even if  NTIA/RUS decides to proceed through entirely conventional means, the procurement  auction will undoubtedly provide important lessons (e.g., bidder receptiveness to  quantitative targets) that will inform refinements to the conventional approach.   V. Conclusion  A traditional grant application review process may prove to be inadequate to the herculean  task of distributing broadband stimulus grants.  It is likely to be slow, cumbersome, and  will result in a suboptimal allocation of resources.  By contrast, competitive bidding,  through the use of procurement auctions, can allocate the funds quickly and efficiently.  While we advocate using procurement auctions to distribute all of the broadband stimulus  money, allocating even a portion of the funds using procurement auctions would be useful  as an experiment.  At a minimum, the broadband stimulus funds present a golden  opportunity to implement rigorous evaluation techniques, which will generate knowledge  that can be applied to other current and future programs.  To that end it is important to  include procurement auctions as one approach to be tested.  11    Respectfully submitted,  Daniel Ackerberg  lifornia, Los Angeles University of Ca   ames Alleman  lorado  J University of Co   enneth Arrow  ersity  K Stanford Univ   usan Athey  ity  S Harvard Univers   onathan Baker  sity  J American Univer   illiam Baumol  ity  W New York Univers on    oleman BazelC Brattle Group    imothy Bresnahan  rsity  T Stanford Unive   eremy Bulow  iversity  J Stanford Un   Jeff Carlisle    eon?Koo Che  rsity  Y Columbia Unive   eter Cramton  land  P University of Mary   regory Crawford  ick  G University of Warw   erald Faulhaber  f Pennsylvania  G University o   eremy Fox  niversity of Chicago  J U   Jacob Goeree  ute of Technology  California Instit   rent Goldfarb  land  B University of Mary   hane Greenstein   University  S Northwestern   obert Hahn   University  R Georgetown   obert Hall  rsity  R Stanford Unive   ard Hanson  ersity  W Stanford Univ   arry Harris  orporated  B Economists Inc   obert Harris  California  R University of    anice Hauge  rth Texas  J University of No   erry Hausman  tts Institute of Technology  J Massachuse   ohn Hayes  sociates  J Charles River As   Thomas Hazlett  niversity    George Mason U en Hendricks  as  K University of Tex   rishna Jayakar  University  K Penn State    John Kagel  Ohio State University  12      lfred Kahn  rsity  A Cornell Unive   lan Kremer  rsity  I Stanford Unive   ijay Krishna  rsity  V Penn State Unive   homas Lenard  cy Institute  T Technology Poli   onathan Levin  ity  J Stanford Univers   uanchuan Lien  nstitute of Technology   Y California I   ohn Mayo  ersity  J Georgetown Univ   avid McAdams  ty  D Duke Universi   aul Milgrom  iversity  P Stanford Un   oger Noll  ersity  R Stanford Univ   ruce Owen  ersity  B Stanford Univ   harles Plott  tute of Technology  C California Insti   obert Porter  n University  R Northwester   hilip Reny  ago  P University of Chic   regory Rosston  tanford University  G S   David Salant  ool of Economics Toulouse Sch   cott Savage  do  S University of Colora     illiam SamuelsonW Boston University    ichard Schmalensee  titute of Technology  R Massachusetts Ins   arius Schwartz  niversity  M Georgetown U   oav Shoham    Y Stanford University   ndrzej Skrzypacz  rsity  A Stanford Unive   ernon Smith  sity  V Chapman Univer   rett Tarnutzer B BT Consultancy    ichael Topper  search  M Cornerstone Re   aniel Vincent  aryland  D University of M   oel Waldfogel  nnsylvania  J University of Pe   cott Wallsten  licy Institute  S Technology Po   obert Weber  versity  R Northwestern Uni   radley Wimmer  vada, Las Vegas  B University of Ne   Karen Wrege  13    KBEnterprises      Lixin Ye  Ohio State University      Federal Communications Commission FCC 10-58 65 APPENDIX C Omnibus Broadband Initiative, The Broadband Availability Gap Federal Communications Commission FCC 10-58 217 STATEMENT OF CHAIRMAN JULIUS GENACHOWSKI Re: Connect America Fund, WC Docket No. 10-90, A National Broadband Plan for Our Future, GN Docket No. 09-51, High-Cost Universal Service Support, WC Docket No. 05-337 This item is an important milestone in our deeply important effort to ensure that every American, no matter where they live or what they earn, has access to affordable, high-quality broadband communications service. It will not be easy. But that is what we are committed to do. It is necessary that we do so to promote economic growth, job creation and broad opportunity for all Americans in the 21st Century. Last month, the Commission delivered to Congress a plan to promote world-leading communications infrastructure in the United States – to match, and surpass, broadband deployment in other countries with which we compete. One of the key components of the National Broadband Plan – and the Commission Joint Statement on Broadband – was comprehensive reform of the universal service program. Today’s item is the first in a series of proceedings to implement that vision. This proceeding will lay the groundwork for a system that provides universal service support for broadband and voice services in an efficient and targeted manner. Today’s Notices suggest common- sense reforms to cap growth and cut inefficient funding of voice networks. And they seek comment on the use of a model to assist with determining levels of universal service support for broadband communications, so that rural and other carriers, which have done so much to provide basic telephone service to Americans who otherwise would not have it, can provide 21 st Century communications services to those Americans. That support must be sufficient to ensure that providers can offer quality broadband service to high cost areas, without unfairly burdening those who ultimately bear the costs of universal service. The comprehensive universal service reform that the National Broadband Plan envisions will take time, but cannot take too long. We do not want flash cuts. We want a reasonably paced and certain approach to converting universal service to broadband communications. That is why the Plan sets out a step-by-step approach, suggesting that the Commission begin with action, and act steadily and consistently as we work with all stakeholders to get the job done. This item begins that process by seeking the best way to create an accelerated process to fund deployment of broadband networks in unserved areas, while the Commission works on fully implementing the new Connect America Fund. I thank the staff for their hard work on this item, and I look forward to working with my colleagues to make affordable, high-quality broadband available to all Americans. Federal Communications Commission FCC 10-58 218 STATEMENT OF COMMISSIONER MICHAEL J. COPPS Re: Connect America Fund, WC Docket No. 10-90, A National Broadband Plan for Our Future, GN Docket No. 09-51, High-Cost Universal Service Support, WC Docket No. 05-337 I approve both the NOI and the NPRM before us as the Commission makes good on its pledge to be fast-off-the-mark in implementing the National Broadband Plan. The comprehensive reform of the Universal Service Fund is, as we’ve all known for a long time, integral to getting broadband ubiquitously deployed and adopted. Today we begin to move in earnest toward a Twenty-first century Universal Service program that delivers for broadband what Twentieth century Universal Service delivered for voice service—and more. Comprehensive reform is never painless and when it comes to building a new Universal Service system, shared sacrifice will be required from just about every stakeholder. Maybe, probably, this is why the Commission has never successfully tackled comprehensive Universal Service reform before. Previous Commissions undertook partial fixes and adjustments to existing USF programs to address discrete problems or contain costs. Sometimes real problems were solved, but at other times this approach had the unfortunate consequence of pushing interested parties apart rather than bringing them to the table to pursue workable, long-term solutions. Today parts of the country have only legacy voice services—sometimes not even that—under the current high-cost Universal Service program, while others have access to truly amazing broadband- capable networks funded indirectly through that same high-cost program. While we often rightly complain about the lapses, we should also recognize the achievements. Regardless of where the funding comes from, I commend those providers who have made broadband deployment a priority. For example, a lot of small rural telcos often went where others feared to tread and brought broadband to some pretty remote places. Their efforts should be not only recognized, but applauded. Now our challenge is to retool the Universal Service system to provide the efficient and targeted support needed to bring high speed, value-laden broadband to all our citizens. The National Broadband Plan commits to such action and today this Commission takes important steps with the NOI and the NPRM. While I am supportive of most of what we do today, the record will show that I have expressed concerns in the past about some of the suggestions put forward here. In particular, as it seeks to develop a detailed analytic foundation for the distribution of Universal Service support, the NOI places strong emphasis on the use of reverse auctions. When I supported the previous Commission’s decision to seek comment on the merits of reverse auctions for distributing Universal Service support, I cautioned that the prospect of using such a mechanism raised many questions that still remain unanswered. For instance, how do we ensure that the winning bidder provides the services for which support is received? What happens if the auction winner decides to discontinue its operation in the supported area? Who will pick up the pieces and how will that be decided? What will be the rules of the road and how will they be established? And enforced? I’m not saying these questions are unanswerable and I am hopeful we will develop an extensive record on these issues, but I do emphasize that answering all these—and I’m sure other—questions and allaying all doubts are the necessary predicates of my support. The NPRM proposes several options for containing the growth of the high-cost Universal Service program. I have been wary of some of the earlier makeshift attempts by the Commission to curtail the overall size of the Universal Service Fund because these efforts have too often served as delay tactics to avoid the tougher challenge of comprehensive reform. Clearly, the situation has changed with this new Commission, and I recognize that the proposals in the NPRM seek to phase out legacy support while we ramp up direct funding for broadband through the Connect America Fund. We need to do this, no question about it. But let’s recognize that many of the proposals in the NPRM—which may very well be necessary and overdue—require major actions that will be burdensome for some, perhaps most, Universal Federal Communications Commission FCC 10-58 219 Service participants. Here, too, compiling a full and viable record is the key to success. And let’s also emphasize that while we are shifting Universal Service to support broadband, at the same time we must make sure that voice service is available nationwide. Go to Indian Country to see how much remains to be done on this score. I commend the Chairman for initiating this very important proceeding in the first month following the birth of the National Broadband Plan. And I thank the staff of the Wireline Competition Bureau for drafting an item that parses out a very complex issue, with, I am sure, more to come. This is the time, more so than any time in the nearly nine years I have been around this place, to truly and comprehensively reform Universal Service. We have the commitment, we have the Plan, and now we begin to implement. This item makes a great start. We begin to glimpse the prize at the end of the road— a first-rate broadband network covering the length and breadth of the nation. Federal Communications Commission FCC 10-58 220 STATEMENT OF COMMISSIONER ROBERT M. McDOWELL Re: Connect America Fund, WC Docket No. 10-90, A National Broadband Plan for Our Future, GN Docket No. 09-51, High-Cost Universal Service Support, WC Docket No. 05-337 Today we take an important first step on our journey toward badly needed Universal Service reform. USF is America’s largest telecommunications subsidy program, which redistributes nearly $9 billion per year. If we have been able to agree on only one thing at the FCC, it is that the Universal Service subsidy system is antiquated, arcane, inefficient and just downright broken. For instance, since 1998 the contribution factor has increased from 5.53 percent to more than 15 percent today. Positive and constructive change must happen as soon as possible. In November of 2008, the Commission came close to a bi-partisan, groundbreaking agreement to resolve many of the most vexing challenges facing not only Universal Service but intercarrier compensation as well. Unfortunately, needless roadblocks were thrown in our way. But today we have an opportunity to regain our momentum and pursue honest, constructive and comprehensive reform for the benefit of American consumers. I therefore support the Notice of Proposed Rulemaking (“NPRM”) and Notice of Inquiry (“NOI”) regarding Universal Service reform now before us. First, the NOI seeks comments as to whether the Commission should use a cost model for a new support mechanism for broadband. And, if so, the NOI seeks comments on how a model should be structured. Second, the NPRM seeks comments on potential ways to contain the growth of the fund through cuts in the existing system, putting out for comment the cuts that were outlined in the Broadband Plan and also soliciting additional ideas. I am encouraged and pleased that we are seriously examining the possible benefits of employing reverse auctions. As I have mentioned over the years, comprehensive Universal Service reform must adhere to five basic principles. The Commission should: (1) contain the growth of the Fund; (2) in a limited and fiscally sound manner, explore the possibility of broadening the base of contributors; (3) reduce the contribution burden; (4) ensure competitive neutrality; and (5) eliminate waste, fraud and other abuses of the system. To achieve effective and meaningful Universal Service reform, the Commission will need to engage in a complex analysis of potential costs surrounding any changes to the fund. Today’s NPRM and NOI start that process. I thank the Chairman for his leadership in this area. I also thank Sharon Gillett and the diligent team in the Wireline Bureau for your tireless work on these issues. I look forward to working with you and my colleagues on an expeditious, transparent and fair process in pursuit of sensible reforms. Federal Communications Commission FCC 10-58 221 STATEMENT OF COMMISSIONER MIGNON L. CLYBURN Re: Connect America Fund, WC Docket No. 10-90, A National Broadband Plan for Our Future, GN Docket No. 09-51, High-Cost Universal Service Support, WC Docket No. 05-337 With this item we embark upon an ambitious and long-overdue mission: the comprehensive reform of our universal service system to support broadband in geographic areas where there is no business case to deploy or operate broadband. In order for us to successfully accomplish this mission, we must begin with a good road map. The item before us identifies the issues to consider when devising our map. I thank the staff for their hard work in identifying these issues in the National Broadband Plan and for their effort on this item. While the start of any journey can be very exciting, it also can be fraught with anxiety. I recognize there are many reasons for industry to be apprehensive. However, I hope as we begin the discussion of how to design a new support system and realize cost savings in our current system that we remain focused on our essential goal of fully connecting all Americans to voice and broadband services. Federal Communications Commission FCC 10-58 222 STATEMENT OF COMMISSIONER MEREDITH A. BAKER Re: Connect America Fund, WC Docket No. 10-90, A National Broadband Plan for Our Future, GN Docket No. 09-51, High-Cost Universal Service Support, WC Docket No. 05-337 As I have said many times, I believe that it is critical that we move toward comprehensive reform of the Universal Service Fund, targeted to broadband investment. As a nation, we need to transition to a support mechanism that is effective, efficient, and sustainable for areas where market forces are not sufficient to drive broadband services to America’s consumers. The Notice before us is an important first step down that road. Universal service reform will be a challenging—and perhaps sometimes frustrating—endeavor. I have expressed concerns about the ballooning size of the Fund and I am convinced that some hard choices will have to be made to keep it under control. But I am convinced that we have a window of opportunity to finally make the changes that this program desperately needs. I also strongly support seeking comment on the possible implications of using a cost model in a new support mechanism for broadband and I hope to see active participation from all sectors of industry and the public. Building a strong record to be the foundation for reform is always important—but never more so than when we consider whether to adopt, and if so, how to structure a cost model. I look forward to working with the Chairman and my fellow commissioners to tackle universal service reform, and I would like to thank the staff for their thoughtful work on this item.